1/4
Looks like no tags are added yet.
Name | Mastery | Learn | Test | Matching | Spaced |
---|
No study sessions yet.
Q1 — If house prices in a city have doubled in 10 years, what factors might explain this?
Thesis: House prices rise due to a combination of demand, supply, and macroeconomic factors.
Demand-side factors: Population growth, rising incomes, low mortgage rates, migration, speculative investment, or foreign buyers. Example: London house prices surged due to international investment and low interest rates post-2008.
Supply-side factors: Planning restrictions, limited land availability, construction delays, and greenbelt policies constrain housing supply.
Macroeconomic factors: Inflation, interest rates, and economic cycles influence affordability and investment returns.
Speculative behaviour: Perception of housing as a safe investment fuels rapid price increases.
Conclusion: Doubling prices likely reflects structural supply constraints combined with strong demand and macroeconomic conditions; understanding the drivers is key for policy responses.
Q2 — If farmland is producing declining yields, what options should policymakers consider?
Thesis: Declining yields require interventions on technology, resource management, and incentives.
Agricultural technology: Introduce high-yield or drought-resistant crops, precision farming, irrigation improvements.
Sustainability measures: Soil restoration, crop rotation, organic fertilisers, or agroforestry to improve long-term productivity.
Economic incentives: Subsidies for sustainable practices, market support for high-value crops, or investment in rural infrastructure.
Policy adjustments: Protect farmland from urban encroachment, manage water and fertiliser use, and address climate impacts.
Conclusion: Declining yields can be addressed through a combination of technological, ecological, and economic policies, balancing short-term production with long-term sustainability.
Q3 — Imagine a greenbelt around a city. What are the pros and cons of relaxing restrictions on development?
Thesis: Relaxing greenbelt restrictions is a trade-off between housing supply and environmental/social objectives.
Pros: Increases housing supply, can reduce prices, supports urban expansion, may improve infrastructure efficiency.
Cons: Loss of open space, ecosystem degradation, risk of urban sprawl, reduced recreational land. Example: Debate around London’s greenbelt expansion highlights tension between affordability and environmental protection.
Mitigation: Encourage high-quality, higher-density development, retain ecological corridors, and offset greenbelt loss with urban green spaces.
Conclusion: Relaxation may be justified to alleviate housing shortages, but should be done carefully to preserve environmental and social benefits.
Q4 — If a government introduces a new land tax, how would you expect the property market to respond?
Thesis: Property markets respond to land taxes depending on elasticity, speculation, and investment incentives.
Price adjustment: Higher taxes on land reduce speculative gains, may moderate price growth, and shift investment to more productive uses.
Supply effects: Landowners may develop or sell underutilised land, increasing housing supply.
Distributional effects: Costs may be partially passed to tenants; progressive design (e.g., land-value taxation) can minimise negative impacts. Example: Denmark and Singapore have effectively used land taxation to capture unearned gains.
Behavioural responses: Investors might shift to different locations or asset classes if taxes are too high.
Conclusion: A land tax typically moderates speculation and encourages efficient use, but careful design is needed to avoid unintended displacement effects or market distortion.
Q5 — How would you measure whether an urban planning policy has been “successful”?
Thesis: Success should be evaluated using quantitative and qualitative metrics, aligned with policy objectives.
Quantitative indicators: Housing supply and affordability, public transport usage, congestion reduction, land-use efficiency, environmental metrics (air quality, green space coverage).
Qualitative indicators: Resident satisfaction, community cohesion, aesthetic and cultural preservation, inclusivity.
Comparative analysis: Benchmark against objectives, historical trends, or similar cities. Example: Evaluating a new transit corridor might include ridership data, property value changes, and resident surveys.
Dynamic assessment: Consider long-term resilience and adaptability to future needs, not just immediate outputs.
Conclusion: A successful policy combines measurable improvements with broader social, environmental, and economic outcomes, reflecting both efficiency and equity.