Data analysis/ problem solving

0.0(0)
studied byStudied by 0 people
full-widthCall with Kai
GameKnowt Play
learnLearn
examPractice Test
spaced repetitionSpaced Repetition
heart puzzleMatch
flashcardsFlashcards
Card Sorting

1/4

encourage image

There's no tags or description

Looks like no tags are added yet.

Study Analytics
Name
Mastery
Learn
Test
Matching
Spaced

No study sessions yet.

5 Terms

1
New cards

Q1 — If house prices in a city have doubled in 10 years, what factors might explain this?

Thesis: House prices rise due to a combination of demand, supply, and macroeconomic factors.

  • Demand-side factors: Population growth, rising incomes, low mortgage rates, migration, speculative investment, or foreign buyers. Example: London house prices surged due to international investment and low interest rates post-2008.

  • Supply-side factors: Planning restrictions, limited land availability, construction delays, and greenbelt policies constrain housing supply.

  • Macroeconomic factors: Inflation, interest rates, and economic cycles influence affordability and investment returns.

  • Speculative behaviour: Perception of housing as a safe investment fuels rapid price increases.

Conclusion: Doubling prices likely reflects structural supply constraints combined with strong demand and macroeconomic conditions; understanding the drivers is key for policy responses.

2
New cards

Q2 — If farmland is producing declining yields, what options should policymakers consider?

Thesis: Declining yields require interventions on technology, resource management, and incentives.

  • Agricultural technology: Introduce high-yield or drought-resistant crops, precision farming, irrigation improvements.

  • Sustainability measures: Soil restoration, crop rotation, organic fertilisers, or agroforestry to improve long-term productivity.

  • Economic incentives: Subsidies for sustainable practices, market support for high-value crops, or investment in rural infrastructure.

  • Policy adjustments: Protect farmland from urban encroachment, manage water and fertiliser use, and address climate impacts.

Conclusion: Declining yields can be addressed through a combination of technological, ecological, and economic policies, balancing short-term production with long-term sustainability.

3
New cards

Q3 — Imagine a greenbelt around a city. What are the pros and cons of relaxing restrictions on development?

Thesis: Relaxing greenbelt restrictions is a trade-off between housing supply and environmental/social objectives.

  • Pros: Increases housing supply, can reduce prices, supports urban expansion, may improve infrastructure efficiency.

  • Cons: Loss of open space, ecosystem degradation, risk of urban sprawl, reduced recreational land. Example: Debate around London’s greenbelt expansion highlights tension between affordability and environmental protection.

  • Mitigation: Encourage high-quality, higher-density development, retain ecological corridors, and offset greenbelt loss with urban green spaces.

Conclusion: Relaxation may be justified to alleviate housing shortages, but should be done carefully to preserve environmental and social benefits.

4
New cards

Q4 — If a government introduces a new land tax, how would you expect the property market to respond?

Thesis: Property markets respond to land taxes depending on elasticity, speculation, and investment incentives.

  • Price adjustment: Higher taxes on land reduce speculative gains, may moderate price growth, and shift investment to more productive uses.

  • Supply effects: Landowners may develop or sell underutilised land, increasing housing supply.

  • Distributional effects: Costs may be partially passed to tenants; progressive design (e.g., land-value taxation) can minimise negative impacts. Example: Denmark and Singapore have effectively used land taxation to capture unearned gains.

  • Behavioural responses: Investors might shift to different locations or asset classes if taxes are too high.

Conclusion: A land tax typically moderates speculation and encourages efficient use, but careful design is needed to avoid unintended displacement effects or market distortion.

5
New cards

Q5 — How would you measure whether an urban planning policy has been “successful”?

Thesis: Success should be evaluated using quantitative and qualitative metrics, aligned with policy objectives.

  • Quantitative indicators: Housing supply and affordability, public transport usage, congestion reduction, land-use efficiency, environmental metrics (air quality, green space coverage).

  • Qualitative indicators: Resident satisfaction, community cohesion, aesthetic and cultural preservation, inclusivity.

  • Comparative analysis: Benchmark against objectives, historical trends, or similar cities. Example: Evaluating a new transit corridor might include ridership data, property value changes, and resident surveys.

  • Dynamic assessment: Consider long-term resilience and adaptability to future needs, not just immediate outputs.

Conclusion: A successful policy combines measurable improvements with broader social, environmental, and economic outcomes, reflecting both efficiency and equity.