1/113
Looks like no tags are added yet.
Name | Mastery | Learn | Test | Matching | Spaced |
---|
No study sessions yet.
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics (FFTWE)
private market outcomes are pareto-efficient under a broad set of conditions
rational agents
no externalities
complete mkts
symmetric info
perfect comp.
pareto efficiency
no one can be made better off w/out making someone else worse off
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics (SFTWE)
any pareto-efficient allocation can be achieved through a decentralized equilibrium after redistribution, under a broad set of conditions
why gov intervention?
create a framework of law, mkt failures, paternalistic concerns (when indiv. act against their own self interest), redistr.
how do mkts get secure property rights?
police/justice system to ensure that private contracts are enforceable
source of mkt failure
lim rationality, externalities + public goods, asymmetrical info, imperfect info
paternalism critique
positive benefits from gov intervention create lim rationality (ex: social security, mandatory seat belts)
equity-efficiency trade-off
redistr. distorts incentives (ex: to work); lump-sum redistr. not feasible in real world
how does the gov intervene?
through maximizing an objective
how does the gov set a social objective?
organic holistic view: obj. can be defined ex abstracto at the social level
individualist/democratic view (modern pub econ view): attempt to deal with and/or aggregate indiv. preferences.
fundamental conflict btwn social + indiv. choice
aggregation of indiv. preferences may be the best of a set of unsatisfactory alternatives
effects of gov intervention
direct (mechanical) effects: tax raises revenue for gov
indirect (behavioral) effects: with tax, ppl reduce consumption → tax collections fall → DWL
why are optimal policies not always implementable
may lack majority support, first-best policies are not always credible + are costly or difficult to implement because of information, administrative things, ect;
gov failures
policy makers have own objectives that differ from social welfare
marg. utility
incremental utility gained by an additional unit of consumption
marg. rate of substitution (MRS)
rate at which consumers are willing to trade one good for another
describes slope of IC
IC
a curve containing the set of consumption bundles from which the consumer obtains the same level of utility
BC
mathematical representation of all affordable combination of goods; quantity demanded changes as income changes:
normal goods: quantity and income move in the same direction
inferior goods: opposite direction
income effect
tax makes consumers poorer, leading them to reduce consumption of normal goods
substitution effect
tax increases the relative price of good A leading consumers to substitute away from it and towards good B
normal goods
income and substitution effects reinforce each other
inferior goods
income effect moves in the opposite director that substitution effect does but the latter prevails.
giffen good
inferior good for which the income effect prevails
demand curve
describes the quantity of a good consumed at each price
compensating variation (CV)
what change in income would restore the consumer’s well-being to what it was before the price change
equivalent variation (EV)
what change in the consumer’s income would have an equal effect on the consumer’s well-being as the price changes
CV vs EV vs change in CS
no income effect: CV = EV = change in CS
both normal goods: CV > change in CS > EV
one inferior good: CV < change in CS < EV
supply curve
traces quantity of a good that firms are willing to supply at each price
perf. comp
homogeneous goods, full info, small econ of scale (rapid increase in avg costs if firms increase output), no entry or exit barriers
mkt power
the ability of a firm to profitably raise price above MCs
DWL
cost to society due to an ineffic. allocation of resources caused by mkt power
if DWL exists, CS + PS is negative
mkt equil.
S=D; mkt clearing condition
CS
benefit to consumers beyond the equil. price they pay in the mkt
PS
aka profit; benefit to producers beyond the cost of producing
effic. equil.
equil. that max. welfare (min effic. criterion = pareto effic.)
condition for effic. production
MB=MC
utility possibility curve (UPC)
captures trade-off inherent in diff. utility outcomes (similar to BC or PPC)
represents all pareto-effic possibilities → negative slope
Kaldor-Hicks improvement
if winners can compensate the losers
sum cv greater than or equal to 0
after compensation there is a pareto improvement
K-H effic = max Wutilitarian
justifies use of econ growth for welfare
revealed preference
principle that choices are informative about utility
PPC
max amount of s possible for a given level of production I, holding technology and total amount of inputs constant
treatment effect
avg casual effect of a binary (0-1) variable on an outcome of interest; the diff in two potential outcomes
evaluation problem (while finding the casual effect of a policy)
indiv. can only be in one state at the same time
counterfactual outcome is missing
identifying assumptions that remove selection bias
randomized experiments (makes assignment independent of potential outcomes
natural experiment / DiD
IV methods
discontinuity design methods
common trend assumptions
key assumption for any DiD strategy is that the outcome in T and C groups would follow the same time trend in the absence of the treatment.
problems with DiD + natural experiments
composition of T and C groups evolve over time, substitution bias, externalities + general equil. effects
coase theorem
if transaction costs low + sources of damage can be identified, once property rights are completely defined, private bargaining will restore efficiency irrespective of initial assignment of property rights.
cost of bargaining → need lots of agents to bargain → reduce transaction costs through gov
cost of enforcement → high cost of monitoring (econ. of scale), hard to identify exact source of damage (marg. damage unclear)
public solution to externalities
pigouvian correction taxation
regulation
permits (cap + trade)
regulation
ex: reduce pollution to set level or face legal sanctions; same outcome as pigouvian tax if we know effic. quantity
advantages → ease of enforcement, salience/political expedience
disadvantages → dynamics: no incentive to innovate, allocative ineffic. w/ heterogeneity in pollution reduction cost
need to know each firm’s cost + demand function for effic. regulation (not effic. otherwise)
model w heterogeneous costs
optimum outcome is to have the low cost firm do more pollution reduction than the high cost firm
taxes vs regulation solution
uniform quantity regulation not effic. because diff MC of polluting costs per firm
permits/cap + trade
hybrid of regulation + coasian solution because firms w highest MC buy permits, firms that can easily reduce pollution will sell permits
if tot # of permits set to achieve the social optimum → allocative + productive effic. achieved + maintains dynamic incentives to innovate
taxes fixes price vs cap + trade fixes quantity
taxes fixes price vs cap → quantity of pollution adjusts
trade fixes quantity → price of permits adjusts
when accounting for externalities need to know:
costs of damages associated w various levels of the externality-producing activity
cost of reducing the externality-producing activity
the certainty w which we have estimated these costs
general issues w survey data
framing, anchoring, strategic responses
house price capitalization
the net present value of a house is the sum of the discounted flow of future benefits associated w owning it.
public good
non-rival in consumpt. + non-excludable
non-rival in consumpt
one indiv. consumption of a good does not affect another’s opportunity to consume the good
non-excludable
indiv. can’t deny each other the opportunity to consume a good
free rider problem
ineffic. private provision; FFWTE breaks down
when investment has a personal cost but common benefits, individuals will under invest. → bc of free riding, mkt under prov. of pub goods compared to samuelson formula.
why is priv. provision suboptimal?
bc the sum of MRS is H times 1 → greater than MRT
indiv. will invest too little in G → pareto improv. if each indiv. invested more $ in G so MRS = 1/H
samuelson rule: limitations
free riding legitimizes public intervention to reach samuelson rule, but difficult to implement
gov needs to know preferences/reveal them
issue of how to finance the public good if only distortionary taxes availanle
sam. analysis is a first-best benchmark
avaiable policy tools to implement optimal level of public good
public provision w endogeneous private provision of PG
in some cases the priv. sector may provide a pub. good, albeit less than the optimal amount
ex: sanitization + additional security of Times Square by a group of businesses
when this exists it may cause a public provision “crowd out” of private provision based on FR argument
preference revelation
1st fundamental issue is to make sure we can elicit truthful revelation of preferences
how: price mechanism in competitive mkts, but unfeasible for public goods bc FR problem
Clarke-Groves mechanisms
help elicit preferences by setting up side by side payments equivalent to net increase in the surpluses of others in the mkt
but doesn’t guarr. balanced budget (Groves 1977)
relies critically on availability of lump-sum transfers
2nd fundamental issue of aggregating preferences
needs to fulfill 3 conditions:
dominance: if one choice is preferred by all voters, aggregation must be such that this choice is made by society
transitivity: if A is preferred to B, and B pref to C, the aggre. must be such that A is pref to C
independence of irrelevant alternatives: if A is pref to B, then intro of C in the choice set should not change the fact that A is pref to B
condorcet paradox
maj. voting does not lead to stable outcome
mediian voter theorem
w single-peaked preferences, maj. voting produces equilibrium
in general, not pareto-effic.
equil. outcome = the median indiv. pref. on spending for G
diff btwn median and mean of MRS determines the degree of ineffic.
corruption as agency problem
lots of asymm. info + agency issues in poltic. process → moral hazard + corrupt
ownership
def. by residual right of control: who gains the benefit/bears the cost of actions taken outside scope of a contract
privatization vs state provision
priv. when quality can be contractually ensured, innovation + competition matter + gov is ineffic
pub: when quality is hard to monitor; competition is weak (ex: policing, health care)
mkts w asymm info
agents in mkt have private info regarding their own characteristics (adverse selection/hidden info: willingness to pay, cost, quality of product) and behavioral (moral hazards/hidden actions: secret price cut, effort)
info. rents
possessors of priv info can exploit this
Akerlof’s lemon model
always effic. to trade both types of goods, many buyers + sellers, the true quality known to sellers, not buyers
adverse selection
a mkt situtation where worse goods, products, or services get selected over superior ones due to asym. priv. info that prevents the mkt from distnguishign themselves
ex: houses (buyer’s remorse), hiring (job condition known to employer, ability known to the employee)
moral hazard
a mkt situation where an agent chooses inefficient actions bc the mkt can’t observe the agent’s actions and reward the effic. choice (or punish ineffic)
ex: reckless behav. ensured by emploers, risky invest by fund agents, embezzlement
when consumers can’t observe quality, firms have no incentive to provide it and choose the cheape,r lower quality opt → ineffic, unless quality can be credibly signaled
risk adversion + insurance
insurance is valuable because of risk adversion from dimin. marg. util.
consumption smoothing
indiv. desire consumption smoothing → maintaining a stable level of consumpt. over time, even when their inc. fluctuates
single crossing condit.
low risk type’s IC is always steeper
separating equilibrium
two insurance contracts offered
pooling equilibrium
only one insurance contract is offered
social insurance (SI)
gov intervention to provide insurance against adverse events; citizens “buy” through taxes or mandatory contributions (typically not M-T); can compel indiv. to participate → ensures insurance for everybody at the actuarially fair rate for the whole pop.
main types: unemploy. insurance, disability insurance, health insurance, SS
manditory SI @ one price can create a pareto improvement
Probs. w SI
1) crowding out: a) may crowd out existing forms of private insurance b) the availability of priv insurance determines the extend of crowd out and hence the value of SI
2) moral hazard: a) another asymm. info prob b) adverse (and unobservable) actions taken by indiv. in resp. to insurance
3) classification errors type 1 (a truly eligible indiv. applies for benefits but is rejected) and type 2 (ineligible; accepted)
types of moral hazard
1) reduced precaution against entering the adverse state
2) increased propensity of claiming the adverse state
3) increased expenditures when in adverse state
4) supplier responses to insurance against adverse state
cost of moral hazard
creates adverse responses to SI → two kinds of externalities
1) insurance program becomes more expensive → higher premium/taxes for all insured indiv.
2) often an insurance claim (e.g. in UI and DI) is associated with lower labor supply → reduces tax rev. for other productive uses
^^ both create effic. cost
unemploy. insurance (UI)
provide cash benefits to workers suffering involuntary job losses. benefits are a functoon of pre-unemploy. earnings
moral hazard in UI
i) an effect on the incidence of unemploy
ii) an effect on the duration of unempoy.
*hard to estimate effect of UI since they are national so hard to define T or C groups
SS
smooths consumpt. + provides insurance against lost of earnings at older age (or disability)
in many countries: large SI program, fast growing major fiscal imbalance
indiv. failures
indiv. may not save adequately for retirement on their own (info + self-control problems)
indiv failures: paternalism
gov imposes its preferences against indiv. → indiv. should oppose gov program
indiv failures: behavorial
indiv. understand that they have probs. + welcome gov intervention
redistr within generations
retirement programs can redistr. based on life-time earnings (instead of annual)
redistr across generations
retirement programs can redistr. across cohorts (so does gov. debt)
pub. pensions
indiv. pay SS contributions (payroll taxes) while working and receive retirement benefits when thhey stop workign till the end of their life (annuity)
fully funded pension
savings used to pay future benefits, contributions are invested in assets, returns are credited to the scheme’s fund
PAYG pension
contributions from today’s workers pay benefits for today’s retirees, contractian in nature, run by the state, allows for redistr. + insurance across generations, legacy debt
rate of growth > interest rate: every generation could receive more than it contributes (Samuelson 1958)
legacy debt
first generation receives benefits without contributing
defined contribution scheme
accumulate contribu. + returns in account used to finance/calcuate pension depends on:
how much you and your employer pay in
investment performance
*retirees bear risk: real rates of return to assets, future earnings trajectories, future pricing of annuities
defined benefit schemes
pays a guaranteed income in retirement usually based on 1) final or avg salary 2) # of years worked
wage hist. + length of service are used to calc. pension
sponsor (= tax payers) bear risk of adverse outcomes
SS + labor
insurance may reduce labor supply (moral hazard)
imperfect info + healthcare
adverse selection: only sick ppl buy insurance
heterogeneous + unobservable health risks
fixed price of insurance; ppl w higher risk buy insurance
prices must be high to cover insurer’s costs
mkt offer less than full insurance