1/73
Looks like no tags are added yet.
Name | Mastery | Learn | Test | Matching | Spaced |
---|
No study sessions yet.
Reasons to estimate consumer demand systems
Welfare analysis (from price changes)
Cost of living indices
See how consumers substitute goods in response to price changes (also linked to welfare analysis)
Demand system
A system of equations linking price and quantity demanded of goods that must be derived as the solution of a consumer problem for a given utility function.
I.e. demand systems must be invertible - not every equation system that links quantities and prices is a demand system.
CES utility - finding EQ demand
CES utility:
Take FOCs for x0 and xj to obtain expressions for marginal utilities
Then divide the FOC wrt good j by the FOC wrt good 1 to obtain an expression for xj in terms of prices and good 1, then replace this in the BC.
Solve for x1 in terms of x0, then solve for x0 in terms of parameters and income.
Axioms for Economic Rationality
Reflexivity - any bundle is always weakly preferred to itself (trivial but required)
Completeness - any two bundles of goods can be compared (no bundles are outside the preference ordering)
Transitivity - if a is preferred to b and b is preferred to c, c cannot be preferred to a
Continuity - If x⪰y , then there exists a bundle z close to x such that z⪰y; and similarly if y⪰x
Non-satiation (monotonicity) - more of any good is always preferred to less
Weak axiom of revealed preferences (WARP)
If A and B are feasible and a person chooses A, a change in prices that causes A and B to still be feasible should not cause B to be chosen over A.
Properties of Marshallian demand
Adding up: BC always binds due to non-satiation
Homogeneity: no money illusion - if income and prices rise by the same proportion, consumption won’t change
Engel Curves
Show how demand changes has income changes, generated by fixing prices and looking at demand as a function of income.
Key point is that different goods have different slopes, so income elasticities cannot be constant for all goods
Dual approach for obtaining demand systems (i.e. expenditure minimisation problem)
Different to ‘primal approach’ utility maximisation problem used to create a Marshallian demand system
Duality of this approach is shown through the fact that the indirect utility (utility resulting from UMP for Marshallian demand) is the same as the fixed utility level for the EMP only if the resulting cost function (costs resulting from solving the EMP for Hicksian demand) is equal to income.
Properties of cost functions
Homogeneous of degree 1 in prices
Continuous in prices and utility
Non-decreasing in prices, strictly increasing in utility for positive prices
Concavity in prices (ensures negative definiteness of the SOC)
Satisfies Shephard’s lemma:
Deriving the Slutsky equation
Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS): process for estimation
Take derivative of log cost function wrt. log p to get an expression for the income share of each good (Shephard’s lemma)
Use duality at the optimum (cost function = income) to sub in y where possible
Final system should have the following form:
Approximate P with the Stone Index
Add an i.i.d. error to each household’s equation in the system, and estimate parameters using simple regression on a micro dataset (prices, incomes, demand levels)
General formula for a cost of living index
Every utility function will give a different CoLI, since you need to decide the initial representative basket of goods
CoLI with Cobb-Douglas preferences
Solve for Marshallian demands to get indirect utility then solve for the cost function
Key points:
Independence of base - P does not depend on utility levels
Normalising parameters to alpha + beta = 1, setting prices in the base year equal to 1, and then taking logs of P gives the following:
Ln(P) is a geometric mean weighted by budget shares, i.e. it is the Stone Price Index.
P measures the CoL assuming that the effect of a price change depends on the share consumers spent on goods 1 and 2 (not the actual amounts they spend)
CoLI with Stone - Geary preferences
Why isn’t comparing indirect utility a useful measure of welfare costs from a price change
Any monotonic transformation of the utility function will yield different indirect utilities, and hence a different welfare cost (despite giving the same optimal consumption bundle)
Money metric indirect utility functions
Compensating Variation as a £ measure of welfare costs
Amount of money needed to compensate an individual for a change in prices so that their utility remains the same as it was before.
First term is equal to income (cost function at t = 1 prices and t = 1 utility) due to duality
Additionally:
Amount of money needed to compensate an individual for a change in prices so that their utility remains the same as it was before. First term is equal to income (cost function at t = 1 prices and t = 1 utility) due to duality:
Additionally:
Compensating variation graphs (demand curves and indifference curves)
Equivalent variation
Amount of money needed for an individual at the original prices to make them as well off as after the price change.
In this case, income is the second term - so EV is the difference between the cost of today’s utility at yesterday’s prices and today’s income:
Equivalent Variation diagrams
Comparison between EV and CV
Higher utility shifts the Hicksian demand curve to the right if normal, and to the left if inferior (always holds since the cost function is strictly increasing in the level of utility)
The difference between EV and CV is driven by income effects, since for EV the indirect utility being used is the same between cost functions (whereas for CV the comparison points are on different indifference curves). Therefore for a utility function without income effects (i.e. quasi-linear preferences) EV = CV.
EV and CV size comparison for normal and inferior goods
Consumer surplus
Area under the Marshallian demand curve:
With no income effects, CV = EV = change in CS
With income effects, change in CS lies between EV and CV
It is the most common welfare measure, and is an intermediate measure between CV and EV, but doesn’t have an immediate interpretation in terms of utility theory
Laspeyres price index
Under Leontief utility (perfect complements - the representative basket is always consumed in the same ratio
This is an ideal index - chooses some level of utility and asks how much more expensive is it to achieve that utility when the prices change
Paasche price index
Key difference between Paasche and Laspeyres: Paasche uses utility at t = 1 as the base (‘ideal’) utility, whereas Layspeyres uses utility at t = 0
Over and underestimation results for Laspeyres and Paasche when preferences are not restricted to being Leontief
Laspeyres overestimates compensating variation
Paasche underestimates equivalent variation
Laspyeres and CV: Diagram
Paasche and EV: Diagram
Estimating CV: First order Taylor approximation
CV can thus be estimated using data on income, consumption shares and prices
Estimating CV: Second order Taylor approximation
The elasticity term captures substitution effects, but now requires that there be price variation in the data when estimating CV
Banks, Blundell and Lewbel (1996) argue that it is empirically necessary to estimate price elasticities to properly evaluate welfare effects of large price changes, but when prices are small, first order approximations perform adequately.
Estimating CV: AIDS
Estimate the almost ideal demand system as gone over in other cards, then back out cost functions to estimate CV. Would need data on income, shares, and prices to estimate the CV, and could not use aggregate data.
2nd Welfare Theorem + why it fails
Any Pareto efficient outcome can be reached by redistribution of endowments and then letting the market run its course
Fails because redistribution of endowments (basically ‘abilities’ is not feasible so the gov’t must use distortionary taxes and transfers, incurring an equity / efficiency tradeoff.
Lump-sum taxation and deadweight loss
Taxes where the burden can’t be reduced by changing consumer behaviour. They are idealised as they imply that taxes only vary with endowment (i.e. ability)
Deadweight loss arises due to the behavioural response to a tax. it is the additional welfare loss of a tax above the revenue it creates. The magnitude of the inefficiency is determined by the extent to which consumers change their behaviour to avoid the tax.
DWL: Diagram (on indifference curves, easily recognisable on supply+demand curves
Derivation of Harberger’s Formula
Deadweight loss formula
Remember, income effects of taxation are non-distortionary (i.e. consistent with second WT). Taxes only become distortionary due to the behavioural response
Tax incidence
Statutory incidence of a tax: doesn’t describe who bears the tax, so does not = economic incidence. Taxes can be shifted since they directly affect prices which affects quantities, which then affects other prices.
Tax incidence is borne by those who cannot easily change their behaviour. Therefore:
Static labour supply model: consumer’s problem
Interior solutions will take the form of:
so the wage rate is the rate at which the consumer is willing to give up leisure in return for additional consumption
Decomposed total effect of a change in w (i.e. the price of leisure)
Income effect: as income increases, workers tend to supply less labour to ‘spend’ the higher income on leisure
Substitution effect: as income rises, the opportunity cost of leisure increases and workers supply more labour
Overall effect depends on which effect dominates, and this may vary for different wage rates (if sub effect is stronger, labour supply curve is upward sloping, opposite true for if the income effect is stronger)
Extensive margin in static labour supply model
Static labour supply: formal derivation of slutsky equation
Blundell, Duncan and Meghir as a key application for labour supply models
Derivation of Slutsky equation for intertemporal choice model
Where R = 1/(1+r)
Pareto conditions (i.e. for an allocation to be Pareto efficient)
MRT is the marginal rate of transformation - equal to the slope of the PPF
Basic policy guidance under general theory of second best
With interdependencies between markets, policy should be guided by the principle that distortions can offset each other and that new distortions can counteract existing ones rather than restoring Pareto conditions in some markets
With no interdependencies between markets, policy should be guided by the principle that Pareto conditions should be satisfied in independent markets (if possible)
James Meade Tariffs (two interdependent markets, one with a removable tariff, one with an irremovable tariff)
Reducing the tariff in market 2 has two effects
Reduction of distortion (DWL) in market 2, which is diminishing marginally the more the tax is removed
Reduction of demand in market 1, so there is lost tariff revenue (constant marginally and equal to the tariff rate)
Ramsey pricing: Government’s problem (max consumer utility subject to their budget constraint)
Find FOCs and sub in consumer’s FOCs from their maximisation problem:
Ramsey pricing: key result (independent markets)
Goods that are elastic in demand should be priced close to marginal cost
Goods that are inelastic in demand should be priced further above marginal cost
It is optimal to price both the public goods above MC (with interdependent markets, it is not optimal to try to set price equal to MC for a good either)
Ramsey rule is a prescription of how to restrict output - the quantity of each good should be reduced proportionately, and by the same percentage
See notes for modified rule with interdependent markets
Diamond and Mirrlees production efficiency: assumptions
Competitive markets: prices taken as given for consumers and producers
Constant returns to scale technology in production of all commodities
Full flexibility in choosing taxes on all commodities and factors of production in the form of wedges
Revenue requirement for the gov’t is R
No lump-sum taxes
Individualistic social welfare function
Non-satiation for at least one good
Diamond and Mirrlees production efficiency: key result
If all of the assumptions hold, the second best optimal tax system maintains the economy on the PPF. This is because with 0 profits, welfare is only determined by consumer prices (and how choices are influenced by them. Hence, any utility level attained with production inefficiency can be attained when the inefficiency is removed, so production inefficiencies only add distortions without correcting others or generating benefits.
So to meet the revenue requirement, distort the consumption side (assumed to be independent of production side) and maintain productive efficiency (doesn’t necessarily mean that you don’t tax producers at all, just means that taxes shouldn’t stop them producing on the PPF)
Basic production efficiency example: diagram
On the ideal (no tax) budget line (q1 = c1) the consumer’s preferred bundle would be A, but that is unattainable (reminder that c1 is equal to the producer’s price due to perfect competition - q1 is the price that the consumer sees)
If we allow for lump sum (non-distortionary) taxation, the consumer’s budget constraint shifts by exactly the same amount as the PPF for the revenue requirement. This gives E(fb) which satisfies all Pareto conditions but is unattainable since only distortionary taxation is possible
Therefore, the government sets the consumption tax at t1, changing the consumer’s BC to B1, which meets the relevant indifference curve at E(sb). This point is on the PPF, maximise consumer utiltiy, but doesn’t meet the Pareto condition of MRS = MRT so is not first best
Setting the tax too high to t’1 woudl result in BC of B2, and a consumer maximisation point of E(ineff) which is below the PPF.
Application of production efficiency result: input taxes
If you tax inputs differently depending on the sector, then the MRTS is not going to be the same between industries, and the economy will not be production efficient. You can reallocate inputs to increase production of both goods.
Ramsey taxation: government’s problem and FOCs
Note we have added the exogenous income term y = 0 to the consumer’s BC so that we can define the indirect utility of consumers
Ramsey taxation - steps breakdown to reaching optimal formula
Sub in Roy’s identity to the FOC
Define Marshallian demand as a function of exogenous income y = 0 to yield a Slutsky eqn that you can sub into the FOC
Rearrange and define theta as social marginal value of income term
Rearrange to get the following result
Final step to get optimal tax formula:
Generalises easily to the many goods case, since Hicksian cross-price elasticities are 0
Roy’s identity
Social marginal value of income - key facts
Ramsey taxation with two equity considerations (i.e. two types of consumer): key result and interpretation
Key terms that are defined in the Ramsey taxation model with equity considerations
where superscript s denotes the consumer’s type (L or H)
Similar to the social marginal value of income before, but this time the private marginal value of income for consumer of type s is weighted by the relevant government weighting.
Can be interpreted as the social marginal value of income for consumer s, considering both the direct welfare effect on the consumer and the indirect effect through changes in government revenue, weighted by the goverment’’s valuation of the welfare of consumer s.
Weighted average of the social marginal values of income across all consumers, with the weights being the shares of consumption of good i.
Reflects how changes in income, mediated through consumption, affect social welfare.
Reason that goods that constitute a large share of the budget of the poor should, ceteris paribus, be taxed at a lower rate
Does the Mirrlees model allow for commodity taxation?
Yes
Mirrlees: single crossing property
Implies that high skilled will never earn less income than the low skilled
Tangency points between the gov’t’s chosen consumption function and the indifference curve of the low skilled cannot be tangency points for the high skilled. High skilled indifference curves are flatter.
Intuitively, single crossing ensures no envy, which allows the gov’t to handle incentive compatibility constraints.
Mirrlees: incentive compatibility restriction
Agents cannot prefer another agent’s bundle to their own, in order to incentivise them to truthfully report their income
Mirrleesian tax problem
Government’s tax design is equivalent to specifying a menu of (x,y) such that i chooses (x(i), y(i)) associated to her optimal marginal tax rate.
Mirrlees: individual’s problem
Therefore the optimal MTR for individual i is as below:
Mirrlees: diagram
Government chooses green line as a consumption function c(y) that must be incentive compatible and satisfy the resource requirement
Mirrlees: Key result
Mirrlees: Intuition that the marginal tax rate cannot be 100% or higher
Downward slopes in the consumption function are not incentive compatible
Mirrlees: Intuition that MTR must be at least 0 (ruling out an earned income tax credit) (simple two agent case)
c² is designed such that, keeping income fixed, the increase in consumption for L is exactly matched by the decrease in H, so aggregate income and consumption stay the same. Since marginal utilities are higher for type L, welfare increases as a result of following this consumption function.
Letting consumers relocate to utilmax positions on c² still does not affect the gov’t’s BC.
Mirrlees: Intuition that MTR on the top earner must be 0 (simple two agent case)
The top consumer now will locate at b so she is better off.
Reducing the MTR to 0 for the top earner is less distortionary, so she works more and earns more income / consumption. If you kept it above 0, top earner would not work, those extra hours. Therefore, the tax revenue is unchanged and the top earner is better off, so it is a Pareto improvement to have a consumption function with slope 1 (0 MTR) on the top earner.
Importantly, this assumes that you can identify your top earner ex ante, and adjust taxes around her. Thus there is limited policy relevance.
Revenue maximising income tax: Laffer curve example
Key point is that this elasticity wrt taxable income can be estimated
Saez optimal top bracket tax rate
Decreases in welfare weight of top bracket earners
Decreases with elasticity of taxable income (efficiency result)
Increases with y^m / y(bar) (note this is endogenous to the tax rate, but can be seen to be roughly constant for incomes above $200K to close to the very top).
With y^m / y(bar) equal to 2, and Diamond derives the following result with Pareto skill distribution:
Optimal top income tax rate with a zero top rate (bounded distribution)
Saez optimal top income tax rate calculation: key steps
Identify dW = dM + dB (balances the need for revenue against distortions)
Work out out mechanical effect dM (changes in revenue)
Work out behavioural response dB (no income effects, substitution only) and rewrite using elasticity of taxable income
Equalise dM and dB to the welfare effect dW, which is calculated as the social marginal value of consumption for top bracket taxpayers multiplied by the mechanical effect dM (this is the direct welfare loss from raising additional revenue from top earners, given the gov’t’s valuation of their consumption)
Rearrange expression and divide by y(bar)
Saez optimal top income tax rate - adding income effects