Economics, Markets & Policy

0.0(0)
studied byStudied by 0 people
full-widthCall with Kai
GameKnowt Play
learnLearn
examPractice Test
spaced repetitionSpaced Repetition
heart puzzleMatch
flashcardsFlashcards
Card Sorting

1/6

encourage image

There's no tags or description

Looks like no tags are added yet.

Study Analytics
Name
Mastery
Learn
Test
Matching
Spaced

No study sessions yet.

7 Terms

1
New cards

Q1: What causes economic inequality between regions?

Answer:
Regional inequality arises from a mix of structural, historical, and policy factors.

  • Structural: Industries cluster in certain areas due to agglomeration economies — London’s finance sector attracts more firms and talent, leaving other regions behind.

  • Historical: Former industrial regions, like the North of England, suffered deindustrialisation and struggled to transition to new industries.

  • Policy: Centralised investment decisions often concentrate resources in capital cities. In contrast, Germany’s federal model spreads growth more evenly.

  • Infrastructure & education gaps widen disparities further.

So regional inequality is not natural or inevitable; it reflects unequal access to opportunity and investment. Policies like “levelling up” in the UK attempt to address this, but success requires long-term commitment to education, transport, and local empowerment.

2
New cards

Q2: Should land be taxed differently to other forms of wealth?

Answer:
Yes — land has unique characteristics that justify differential taxation.

  • Why different: Land is immobile and cannot be hidden offshore. Unlike capital, taxing land doesn’t discourage productivity, because supply is fixed.

  • Benefits: A land value tax (LVT) could reduce speculation, capture unearned gains from public investment (e.g. new train stations), and incentivise efficient use of land. Economists from Adam Smith to Milton Friedman have supported this.

  • Challenges: Valuation of land separate from buildings is technically difficult. Politically, landowners resist such taxes.

  • Case study: Denmark and parts of the US have experimented with LVT; Singapore captures land value increases through government land ownership.

So yes, land should be taxed differently, not to penalise owners, but to fairly redistribute unearned gains and promote efficient land use.

3
New cards

Q3: What economic policies best reduce inequality in housing?

Answer:
The most effective policies combine supply-side expansion with demand-side protections.

  • Supply side: Build more affordable housing through public provision or incentives to developers. Vienna’s large-scale social housing programme is often cited as a success.

  • Demand side: Targeted subsidies for low-income renters, housing benefits, or shared ownership schemes.

  • Regulation: Prevent speculative practices (e.g. empty homes taxes, limits on buy-to-let in overheated markets).

  • Long-term: Reform planning to increase supply elasticity, while ensuring quality standards.

So the best approach is not one single policy, but a portfolio: increasing supply, managing demand, and redistributing access to housing. Without addressing supply, redistributive policies alone will just raise prices further.

4
New cards

Q4: Is GDP still a useful measure of success, or should we use alternatives?

Answer:
GDP is useful but insufficient.

  • Strengths: It captures the total economic output and allows for international comparison. Policymakers rely on it for growth forecasts and budgeting.

  • Weaknesses: It ignores inequality, environmental degradation, and unpaid work. A city may have rising GDP while most residents see no benefit. For example, Ireland’s GDP is distorted by multinational tax arrangements.

  • Alternatives:

    • HDI (Human Development Index) incorporates health and education.

    • GPI (Genuine Progress Indicator) adjusts for environmental costs.

    • Bhutan’s “Gross National Happiness” is more radical, though less precise.

  • Best approach: Use GDP alongside complementary measures, not abandon it.

So GDP is still useful as a baseline, but success should be judged more broadly through a dashboard of indicators reflecting wellbeing, sustainability, and distribution.

5
New cards

Q5: Why do markets sometimes fail in relation to land and resources?

Answer:
Markets fail because land and resources have characteristics that don’t fit the assumptions of perfect markets.

  • Externalities: A factory on private land may pollute neighbouring air and water without paying the cost.

  • Public goods: Parks or wetlands provide benefits (clean air, recreation) that markets can’t capture easily.

  • Immobility: Land can’t move to where it’s needed, so markets may allocate it inefficiently.

  • Monopoly power: Large landowners can restrict supply, raising prices.

  • Information failures: Buyers may lack knowledge of flood risk or soil quality, leading to poor decisions.

So market failures are particularly acute in land, requiring regulation and state intervention to internalise costs and ensure fair allocation.

6
New cards

Q6: How should governments respond to rising property prices?

Answer:
Responses should tackle both demand and supply.

  • Supply side: Accelerate housing construction, reform planning, and incentivise affordable housing. Japan’s flexible zoning has kept Tokyo relatively affordable despite high demand.

  • Demand side: Tighter mortgage regulation, taxes on speculative purchases, and limits on foreign investment in overheated markets. New Zealand, for instance, restricted foreign buyers.

  • Redistribution: Use revenues from property taxes to fund social housing or subsidies for low-income households.

  • Risk: Over-suppressing demand risks harming construction industries or household wealth.

So governments should avoid quick fixes like subsidies alone; instead, they should increase supply elasticity while curbing speculative demand.

7
New cards

Q7: What’s the opportunity cost of prioritising one type of land use over another?

Answer:
The opportunity cost is the foregone benefits of the next best alternative use of land.

For example:

  • Building housing on farmland creates short-term social benefits (affordability), but sacrifices food security and agricultural output.

  • Preserving land for conservation protects biodiversity but may limit urban expansion.

  • Allocating land for infrastructure boosts economic growth, but reduces space for housing or green areas.

The key point is that opportunity cost in land use is irreversible in many cases: once farmland is built on, it rarely returns. This makes planning decisions particularly weighty.

So the concept of opportunity cost in land is not abstract — it is about long-term trade-offs that shape societies for generations.