Looks like no one added any tags here yet for you.
What is market structure?
market structure is the characteristics of a market that may influence behaviour and performance (their output and price)
Characteristics of a market
the number and size of sellers
barriers to entry
extent of product differentiation
number and size of buyers
2 rules for profit maximisation
SHUTDOWN RULE: The firm should shut down if price is less than Average variable cost (in short-run) or LRAC (long-run average costs where all factors are variable)
MARGINAL OUTPUT RULE: If the firm doesn’t shut down it should produce at the level where MR = MC
Assumptions of perfect competition
buyers are price takers (can buy as much as they want without affecting price)
sellers and buyers have complete information
sellers are price takers (sellers output choice won’t impact price as wont trigger reaction from rivals due to low competitive behaviour → firms don’t actively compete with each other)
entry is free AKA no barrier to entry and exit
Perfect competition market structure characteristics
Many small number of sellers
low barriers to entry and exit
undifferentiated identical/ homogenous products (very unrealistic but closest to agricultural goods and primary commodities)
Perfect competition short-run equilibrium
when sellers produce as much as buyers want to purchase and buyers purchase as much as sellers choose to produce (
market price determined by where market supply and demand intersect (graph on left)
a sellers output is determined by seller-specific supply and demand (which is the specific MC and AVC on the right and output is when MC=MR) → profit max, may make supernormal profits, losses or break-even in short-run
supply falls off at min AVC as under this firms would shut down
Long-run equilibrium perfect competition
equilibrium changes in long-run because:
all factors are variable which impacts seller’s costs (LRAC is a flatter curve)
sellers can freely enter and exit market (e.g. if making profits this attracts new sellers which increases market supply and reduces price)
= sellers make normal (zero) profit in the long-run where sellers in market are incentivised to stay and none are incentivised to enter (under assumption firms are profit seeking)
declining industries
low revenues mean firm is unable to afford replacing old equipment with new ones so equipment begins wearing out.
HOWEVER people tend to blame an industry’s decline on this old equipment
so old equipment is often AN EFFECT rather than a cause of an industry’s decline
Long-run industry supply prices
in the long-run the industry supply curve ( may be:
horizontal = constant cost industry occurs when input prices don’t change when output expands or falls
rising/upwards sloping = when as as industry expands its output it needs more inputs and the increased demand for inputs raises their prices, as suppliers costs rises they raise their prices to cover their costs
negatively sloped = when industries supplying their inputs have increasing returns to scale which reduce their prices = suppliers costs fall and may reduce their prices
Allocative efficiency of perfect compeitition
consumer and producer surplus is maximised so perfectly competitive markets allocate resoruces efficiently
monopoly
one dominant seller of a particular good or service, no competition
only producer in an industry so set market prices as firm = market
Monopoly assumptions
the monopolist is a price maker (influences price by changing output → means demand curve is downwards sloping + no competition as large market power to change price)
high barriers to entry (even in long-run potential sellers aren’t free to enter market → barriers may be legal requiring specific qualifications, structural e.g. by lowering AC by producing more so new firms who start by producing more can’t reap same profits, strategic behaviour to deter rivals
Monopoly market structure
One large seller
high barriers to entry
differentiated unique product
Monopoly equilibrium
determined by profit maximisation so where MR=MC
trace up to find cost on AC curve and price on AR curve
marginal revenue lies under AR
profits are sustained in the long-run and give incentive for research and development and finding new technologies
consumer and producer surplus
consumer surplus: the difference between the amount consumers are willing to pay and what they actually pay (difference between demand curve and price)
producer surplus: the difference between the price of a good and the minimum price producers are willing to supply it (difference between supply curve and price)
Comparing monopoly to perfect competition
total welfare (consumer + producer surplus) is greater under perfect competition than under monopoly
monopoly has welfare loss → creates rational case for government intervention to prevent formation of monopolies or control their behaviour
Revenue curves and elasticity
when marginal revenue = 0, elasticity of AR is 1 and TR is maximised → will always produce on elastic part of demand curve as want high revenue to maximise profits
when MR is positive, TR rises by more, so elasticity of AR is larger than 1
When MR is negative, TR falls so elasticity of AR is inelastic (between 0 and 1)
price discrimination
when a seller charges different prices for different units of the SAME product or service for reasons not associated with differences in cost
e.g. cinema tickets for children, students and adults, airline tickets on different dates
the ability to charge multiple prices (such as charging higher prices to those willing to pay more) gives the seller the ability to increase consumer surplus and decrease welfare loss
price discrimination allows firms to sell more without decreasing market price
cartels
when firms in an industry agree to cooperate with one another and behave as a singe seller/monopoly to maximise joint profits by eliminating competition
e.g. agree to set quota on output so produce at Q1 instead of Q0 equilibrium, which maximises profits
problems cartels face
ensuring all members follow behaviour that will maximise the industry’s joint profits (rather than succumbing to self interest)
preventing the profits being eroded by the entry of new firms
price discrimination vs single price
price discrimination is more profitable and has no welfare loss
conditions necessary for profitable price discrimination?
sellers must be price makers → in order to set the different prices
buyers must differ and sellers must be able to identify the different buyers in order to discriminate prices
consumers must not be able to participate in arbitrage (when buyers charged a low price purchase the good and resell it e.g. students cant resell to non-students due to proof of student status needed)
Assumptions of price discrimination
the seller is a pure monopolist (price discrimination can occur in markets with more than one seller but assume its a monopolist to understand problem without complications)
entry is blocked even in long-run so analysis doesn’t change between short-run and long-run
Types of price discrimination and definitions
First degree price discrimination: when sellers charge each individual buyer the maximum price the buyer is willing pay
second degree price discrimination: a seller can use a menu of ‘non-linear tariffs’ (non-linear when average price changes) to get buyers to reveal their preferences when they select a tariff e.g. £10 per month vs 5p per minute for calls
third degree price discrimination: when a seller can identify groups of buyer and charge different prices to each group (can be grouped by characteristics such as students, or by location e.g. affluent areas charged more)
first degree price discrimination and diagram
Marginal revenue is equal to Average revenue (= price)
therefore there is no deadweight loss
produces same output as a perfectly competitive seller = more than what it would without price discrimination → more profitable
since every consumer is paying maximum there is no consumer surplus (no difference between what they pay and what they are willing to) so maximum welfare is fully producer surplus
third degree price discrimination and diagram
different markets/groups have different elasticities
groups willing to pay more will have inelastic demand (market X) → benefit without price discrimination as offered lower prices to accommodate for elastic demand
groups not willing to pay as much will have elastic demand (market Y)
total market will add the market curves together horizontally so MC =MR on total market aligns with a point on MRy and MRx
produces same output as without price discrimination, deadweight loss as AR (D) is above MR
price charged in single price monopolist lies between the prices charged to the two groups
linear vs non-linear tariff
low users will prefer linear tariff
high-users will prefer non-linear tariff
forms of imperfect competition
monopolistic competition
oligopoly
2 ways products can be differentiated
horizontal differentiation: same quality (so similar/same price) but choices depend on peoples tastes and preferences
vertical differentiation: quality (and also price) clearly differs
Assumptions regarding monopolistic competition
buyers are price takers
buyers and sellers have complete information
sellers are price MAKERS (so seller sells more when price is lower and their output choice isn’t reacted to by rivals)
entry is free so potential sellers can enter market in the LONG run
Monopolistic competition market structure
many small sellers
low barriers to entry
differentiated products either horizontal or vertical
Short run equilibrium monopolistic competition
price maker so downward sloping demand curve
long run equilibrium monopolistic competition
in long run other sellers can freely enter the market and all factors are variable which impacts sellers costs
long-run costs curves LRAC and LRMC are flatter
make normal profit in long run as when firms enter the market (more sellers) this leads to lower demand for an individual seller as there are the same amount of buyers between a larger amount of sellers
differences between monopolistic competition and perfect competition
price-cost margin: in perfect competition price is always equal to marginal cost but in monopolistic competition price is above marginal cost
capacity: perfectly competitive sellers operate at FULL CAPACITY as they produce at the minimum efficient scale (lowest possible cost) no matter how much they produce whilst monopolistically competitive sellers have EXCESS CAPACITY as firms can produce more to lower their costs
game theory and terms definitions
used to highlight strategies to maximise gains/minimise losses
helps make predictions about how economic agents will behave in certain situations
players → decision makers aka sellers
strategies → pricing decisions
payoffs → how well players do e.g. profits
representation of games
extensive form = sequential move games where player A moves first then player B moves, game represented as a tree diagram
normal form = players move simultaneously, game represented by matric (more strategies (aka choices) = larger matrix 2×2, 3×3 etc.
dominant strategy
a strategy is dominant if it provides a player with the highest payoffs regardless of a opponents strategy
can have dominant strategy equilibrium if both players dominant strategy (highest payoff) is at same point (here would be up left)
nash equilibrium
when no player can do better than their chosen strategy given their beliefs of how other players will play
two requirements:
each player must be playing a best response against their belief of how other players will play
these beliefs must be correct
(in image nash equilibrium where both are underlined as both players playing best response to others strategy)
subgame perfection
refinement of nash equilibrium for sequential move games
split tree map into subgames (e.g. what B does if A chooses up)
use backwards induction in each subgames where you start at end of game to solve for best responses
put extra arrows at best choice, nash equilibrium when arrow goes from both A and B
models of oligopolies
quantity setting (Cournot)
price setting (Bertrand)
Assumptions of oligopolies
buyers are price takers
buyers and sellers have complete information
sellers are price makers → output choice triggers reactions from rivals + demand curve downwards sloping
entry is blocked even in long run
oligopolies market structure
few large sellers (each seller must be large enough to affect price and have rivals large enough to respond)
high barriers to entry
products can be identical or differentiated
Assumptions for Cournot’s model of oligopoly
assumes only 2 sellers in market who compete in quantities and make their output decisions simultaneously
further entry into market is completely blocked
firms produce homogenous products (simplifies model)
the markets demand is P = a - Q (where Q = Qa + Qb → from firm A and B)
Cournot Nash equilibrium
when no firm wants to change its output level holding both output levels constant
equilibrium is at the intersection of both firms best response functions on a diagram
(made up of tracing the different output levels using the marginal output rule MC=MR and the differing demand curves based on what the the other firm produces)
residual demand curve
a firms demand curve given the output of its rivals
the more firms B produces the closer firm A’s residual demand curve is to the origin
constructing Cournot best response functions
made up of tracing the different output levels using the marginal output rule MC=MR and the differing demand curves (original demand versus different residual demand curves) based on what the other firm produces
if firm B doesnt produce anything firm A produces at monopoly output Qm with normal demand curve, if firm B produces Qb1 output is at residual demand curve so firm A produces Qa1 which is lower than Qm.
profit increases as output tends towards the monopoly level
comparing Cournots oligopoly to monopoly and perfect competition
the duopolists ( 2 firms) together produce more than 1 monopolists would produce
the market price is lower than for a monopoly but higher than perfect competition = profit making
Bertrand’s oligopoly model assumptions
there are only 2 firms in the market (duopolists), they choose level of price (compete in prices) and make their pricing decisions simultaneously
further entry into the market is completely blocked
firms have the same constant marginal costs and no fixed costs (which means Total costs = variable costs, and average costs = marginal costs)
firms produce identical products (so buyers purchase from cheapest seller)
market demand: Q = a - P (subtract firm A’s price when its below firm B’s and subtract firms B’s price when PA is above PB)
constant marginal costs
bertrand nash equilibrium
when no firm wants to change its price
equilibrium consists of price pA and pB such that given fir bm B charges pB, firm a profit max price is pA, and given firm A charges pA, firm B’s rpfoit max is pB
the intersection of firm A and B best response functions
Betrand firm specific demand curve and pmax position
if firm believes firm B will set a certain price, under the assumption that their products are identical, consumers will not buy from firm A if their price exceeds that of firm B, so demand curve cuts off at firm B price and is 0 (as firm A sells nothing)
bertrand best response function points explained
Bertrands model compared to monopoly and perfect competition
set a lower price than the monopoly level
market produces more output from the duopoly than under a monopoly
set same price as in perfect competition (no deadweight loss)
bertrands total welfare is consumer surplus
what is the bertrands paradox?
the model claims that by adding only one firm we go from the extreme of monopoly to the other extreme of perfect competition
this is not seen in reality
ways to break the Bertrand paradox
1) if we account for PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION a seller won’t lose all their customers when their rival has a higher price
2) consider CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS as even if all buyers go to the firm with the cheaper price, the firm may not have the ability to supply the whole market
3) acknowledge there is INCOMPLETE INFORMATION about prices and costs so even if a firm has a lower price, consumers may not know so wont all flock to the cheaper firm
4) firms may not compete as intensely as the Bertrand model predicts if they INTERACT REPEATEDLY as they may recognise their ability to charge higher prices if they compete less
what is the prisoners dilemma? solution?
the prisoners dilemma is where the dominant strategy for both players is to act with self interest, but this leads to a nash equilibrium with a less than optimal payoff
to solve this dilemma, players can cooperate to both get a better payofff
however when firms agree to cooperate there are short term incentives to deviate from the agreement to gain an even higher payoff
oligopolies methods of collusion in cournot and bertrand models
for Cournot (quantity setting model) if the firms cooperate they can both produce half of the markets monopoly profit max quantity
for Bertrand (price setting model), both firms can produce at monopoly price
for both there is a short term incentive to produce more than their share of the monopoly quantity to increase profits, or to just undercut the monopoly price by a small amount to encourage more consumers
conditions necessary for oligopolists to collude
1- sellers must interact repeatedly → this means the incentive to deviate from the cooperation agreement will be counteracted by a long-term punishment such as price wars (with price wars the profits from deviating in the long run decrease)
2- sellers must be aware of each others strategies → so will be aware of deviation and bale to punish it, firms may form cartels to monitor firms and make sure they’re each conforming to the agreement
grim trigger strategy
if both firms have decided to cooperate, as soon as one player deviates the firms revert to playing the one-shot nash equilibrium deviate, deviate forever (As trust is lost between the firms so will no longer agree to cooperate)
infinitely repeated prisoners dilemma nash equilbrium
cooperate, cooperate is the forever nash equilibrium if the short term benefit from deviating is less than the long term punishment
short term benefit: difference in payoff between cooperate, cooperate and deviate, cooperate (what they gain by breaking the agreement)
long-term punishment: the difference between a firms payoff from cooperate, cooperate / interest rate (dividing by interest rate helps put future payoffs as present values to represent long-term) and a firms payoff from deviate, deviate / interest rate
finitely repeated prisoners dilemma
can use backwards induction to find a nash equilibrium in each subgame
Supply of labour by an individual worker
supply is upwards sloping (usually) or backwards bending (rarely) depending on which effect dominates:
substitution effect: at higher wages a person will work more as leisure has a greater opportunity cost (losing out on more income with same leisure time)
income effect: higher wages imply worker can afford more leisure time (if dominates = backward bending)
supply of labour to an employer
an employers labour supply depends on whether employer is a wage taker (curve will be perfectly elastic) or a wage maker (upwards sloping)
shifts in supply curves due to:
changes in number of qualified people
non wage benefits attracting employees
changes in slope (responsiveness of supply to wage changes) depends on:
the difficulty of changing jobs
short-run vs long-run