Chapter 18: Antitrust Policy and Regulation
Antitrust policy - Laws and government actions designed to prevent monopoly and promote competition
Industrial regulation - Gov’t regulation of firms’ prices within selected industries
Social regulation - Government regulation of the conditions under which goods are produced, the physical characteristics of goods, and the impact of the production and consumption of goods on society
Historical background
Dominant firms used questionable tactics in consolidating industries + charged high prices to consumers
Society benefits from greater competition
Gov’t used regulatory agencies + antitrust laws to supplement market forces
Sherman Act - Cornerstone of antitrust legislation
Outlawed restraints of trade + monopolization
Courts can prohibit anticompetitive practices + break up monopolists
Not effective, needed more explicit statement
Clayton Act - Strengthened + made clear the intent of the Sherman Act
Outlaws price discrimination
Prohibits tying contracts - Producer requires that a buyer purchase another (or others) of its products as a condition for obtaining a desired product
Prohibits interlocking directorates - Situations where a director of one firm is also a board member of a competing firm—in large corporations where the effect would be reduced competition
Federal Trade Commission Act - Created Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
Cease-and-desist orders - Issued in cases with unfair methods of competition
Wheeler-Lea Act - Amended Federal Trade Commission Act + gave FTC more responsibilities
Celler-Kefauver Act - Amended Clayton Act; prohibited one firm from obtaining the physical assets of another firm when the effect would be reduced competition
Issues + impacts of anti-trust policy
Gov’t has varied in aggression in enforcing antitrust laws
Issues of interpretation
Standard Oil case - Supreme Court found Standard Oil guilty of monopolizing the petroleum industry through a series of abusive and anticompetitive actions
US Steel case - Courts established a rule of reason, saying that not every monopoly is illegal
Alcoa case - Even though a firm’s behavior may be legal, possessing monopoly power violates antitrust laws
Structuralists vs. behavioralists
The relevant market
Courts consider share of market held by dominant firm
DuPont cellophane case - The government contended that DuPont, along with a licensee, controlled 100 percent of the cellophane market. But the Court accepted DuPont’s contention that the relevant market included all “flexible packaging materials”—waxed paper, aluminum foil, and so forth, in addition to cellophane
Issues of enforcement
Individual firms can sue other firms under antitrust laws
Administrations can enforce antitrust laws differently
Active antitrust perspective - Competition is insufficient in some circumstances to achieve allocative efficiency and ensure fairness to consumers and competing firms
Laissez-faire perspective - Antitrust intervention largely unnecessary
Effectiveness of antitrust laws
Firms only sued if it has high market share + evidence of abusive conduct
Microsoft case - Microsoft was found guilty of violating the Sherman Act by taking several unlawful actions designed to maintain its monopoly of operating systems for personal computers
A lower court ordered that Microsoft be split into two competing firms
A court of appeals upheld the lower-court finding of abusive monopoly but rescinded the breakup of Microsoft
Instead of the structural remedy, the eventual outcome was a behavioral remedy in which Microsoft was prohibited from engaging in a set of specific anticompetitive business practices
Overall considered moderately effective
Mergers
Horizontal merger - Merger between two competitors that sell similar products in the same geographic market
Vertical merger - Merger between firms at different stages of the production process
Conglomerate merger - Any merger not horizontal or vertical
Merger guidelines based on Herfindahl index
Most vertical mergers escape antitrust prosecution
Conglomerate mergers generally permitted
Price fixing - An agreement (written, verbal, or inferred from conduct) among competitors to raise, lower, maintain, or stabilize prices or price levels
Per se violations - Collusive activities such as scheming to rig bids on government contracts or dividing up sales in a market
Very commonly persecuted under antitrust law
Price discrimination - The action of selling the same product at different prices to different buyers, in order to maximize sales and profits
Rarely challenged by gov’t
Tying contracts - An agreement in which the seller conditions the sale of one product (the "tying" product) on the buyer's agreement to purchase a separate product (the "tied" product) from the seller
Strictly prohibited
Industrial regulation
Natural monopoly - When economies of scale are so extensive that a single firm can supply the entire market at a lower unit cost than could a number of competing firms
Public interest theory of regulation - Industrial regulation is necessary to keep a natural monopoly from charging monopoly prices and thus harming consumers and society
Problems with industrial regulation
Costs and inefficiency
Perpetuating monopoly long after conditions of natural monopoly have ended
Legal cartel theory of regulation - Practical politicians “supplying” regulation to local, regional, and national firms that fear the impact of competition on their profits or even on their long-term survival. These firms desire regulation because it yields a legal monopoly that can virtually guarantee a profit
Gov’t-sponsored cartel under guise of regulation
Deregulation
Caused lower prices + increased efficiency
Wave of technological advances
Social regulation - Concerned with the conditions under which goods and services are produced, the impact of production on society, and the physical qualities of the goods themselves
Applied to all industries + affects many producers
Intrudes into day-to-day production processes
Expanded rapidly
Antitrust policy - Laws and government actions designed to prevent monopoly and promote competition
Industrial regulation - Gov’t regulation of firms’ prices within selected industries
Social regulation - Government regulation of the conditions under which goods are produced, the physical characteristics of goods, and the impact of the production and consumption of goods on society
Historical background
Dominant firms used questionable tactics in consolidating industries + charged high prices to consumers
Society benefits from greater competition
Gov’t used regulatory agencies + antitrust laws to supplement market forces
Sherman Act - Cornerstone of antitrust legislation
Outlawed restraints of trade + monopolization
Courts can prohibit anticompetitive practices + break up monopolists
Not effective, needed more explicit statement
Clayton Act - Strengthened + made clear the intent of the Sherman Act
Outlaws price discrimination
Prohibits tying contracts - Producer requires that a buyer purchase another (or others) of its products as a condition for obtaining a desired product
Prohibits interlocking directorates - Situations where a director of one firm is also a board member of a competing firm—in large corporations where the effect would be reduced competition
Federal Trade Commission Act - Created Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
Cease-and-desist orders - Issued in cases with unfair methods of competition
Wheeler-Lea Act - Amended Federal Trade Commission Act + gave FTC more responsibilities
Celler-Kefauver Act - Amended Clayton Act; prohibited one firm from obtaining the physical assets of another firm when the effect would be reduced competition
Issues + impacts of anti-trust policy
Gov’t has varied in aggression in enforcing antitrust laws
Issues of interpretation
Standard Oil case - Supreme Court found Standard Oil guilty of monopolizing the petroleum industry through a series of abusive and anticompetitive actions
US Steel case - Courts established a rule of reason, saying that not every monopoly is illegal
Alcoa case - Even though a firm’s behavior may be legal, possessing monopoly power violates antitrust laws
Structuralists vs. behavioralists
The relevant market
Courts consider share of market held by dominant firm
DuPont cellophane case - The government contended that DuPont, along with a licensee, controlled 100 percent of the cellophane market. But the Court accepted DuPont’s contention that the relevant market included all “flexible packaging materials”—waxed paper, aluminum foil, and so forth, in addition to cellophane
Issues of enforcement
Individual firms can sue other firms under antitrust laws
Administrations can enforce antitrust laws differently
Active antitrust perspective - Competition is insufficient in some circumstances to achieve allocative efficiency and ensure fairness to consumers and competing firms
Laissez-faire perspective - Antitrust intervention largely unnecessary
Effectiveness of antitrust laws
Firms only sued if it has high market share + evidence of abusive conduct
Microsoft case - Microsoft was found guilty of violating the Sherman Act by taking several unlawful actions designed to maintain its monopoly of operating systems for personal computers
A lower court ordered that Microsoft be split into two competing firms
A court of appeals upheld the lower-court finding of abusive monopoly but rescinded the breakup of Microsoft
Instead of the structural remedy, the eventual outcome was a behavioral remedy in which Microsoft was prohibited from engaging in a set of specific anticompetitive business practices
Overall considered moderately effective
Mergers
Horizontal merger - Merger between two competitors that sell similar products in the same geographic market
Vertical merger - Merger between firms at different stages of the production process
Conglomerate merger - Any merger not horizontal or vertical
Merger guidelines based on Herfindahl index
Most vertical mergers escape antitrust prosecution
Conglomerate mergers generally permitted
Price fixing - An agreement (written, verbal, or inferred from conduct) among competitors to raise, lower, maintain, or stabilize prices or price levels
Per se violations - Collusive activities such as scheming to rig bids on government contracts or dividing up sales in a market
Very commonly persecuted under antitrust law
Price discrimination - The action of selling the same product at different prices to different buyers, in order to maximize sales and profits
Rarely challenged by gov’t
Tying contracts - An agreement in which the seller conditions the sale of one product (the "tying" product) on the buyer's agreement to purchase a separate product (the "tied" product) from the seller
Strictly prohibited
Industrial regulation
Natural monopoly - When economies of scale are so extensive that a single firm can supply the entire market at a lower unit cost than could a number of competing firms
Public interest theory of regulation - Industrial regulation is necessary to keep a natural monopoly from charging monopoly prices and thus harming consumers and society
Problems with industrial regulation
Costs and inefficiency
Perpetuating monopoly long after conditions of natural monopoly have ended
Legal cartel theory of regulation - Practical politicians “supplying” regulation to local, regional, and national firms that fear the impact of competition on their profits or even on their long-term survival. These firms desire regulation because it yields a legal monopoly that can virtually guarantee a profit
Gov’t-sponsored cartel under guise of regulation
Deregulation
Caused lower prices + increased efficiency
Wave of technological advances
Social regulation - Concerned with the conditions under which goods and services are produced, the impact of production on society, and the physical qualities of the goods themselves
Applied to all industries + affects many producers
Intrudes into day-to-day production processes
Expanded rapidly