Australia's Balance of Payments, Trade, and Exchange Rates (Vocabulary Flashcards)
Page 1
- Australia’s Place in the Global Economy
- Importance of trade to Australia
- Trade = exports + imports
- International trade = exchange of goods and services between nations
- Australia relies on imports for certain products and technologies not produced domestically to assist its own industries
- Direction of trade
- Exports: destination of goods/services (where exports are going)
- Imports: sources of goods/services (where imports come from)
- Composition Of Trade
- Definition: pattern of goods and services traded; types of products exported and imported
- Value of Trade
- Value = volume traded × price
- Prices for each volume depend on import price and export price
- Terms of Trade (TOT)
- Definition: the prices received for exports versus prices paid for imports
- TOT is the ratio of export price to import price, often expressed as a price index
- Formula: ext{TOT}=rac{ ext{Export price index}}{ ext{Import price index}} imes 100
- If TOT index increases, Australia earns relatively more for exports; if it decreases, Australia earns relatively less
- TOT: Examples
- Improvement in TOT: export prices rise faster than import prices
- Example: export price index = 120, import price index = 105
- Calculation: ext{TOT}=rac{120}{105} imes 100 \approx 114.29
- Interpretation: a country can finance a greater volume of imports with existing exports
- Deterioration in TOT: export prices rise less quickly or fall faster than import prices
- Example: export price index = 110, import price index = 115
- Calculation: ext{TOT}=rac{110}{115} imes 100 \approx 95.65
- Interpretation: a country can finance a lower volume of imports with existing exports
- Page 2
- Financial Flows
- International financial flows: movement of capital, money and currencies between countries for investment or business activity
- Key types of flows
- Foreign Direct Investment (FDI): money invested in overseas country with controlling interest (usually ≥ 10% of asset value)
- Development Aid: grants (no repayment) or loans with low interest
- Debt Repayment: repayment of borrowed money with interest
- Portfolio Investment: investment in overseas stocks/bonds/assets without controlling interest (< 10% of asset value)
- Loans: borrowed money expected to be repaid with interest
- Remittances: money international migrants send home
- Financial Derivatives: contracts whose value is based on an underlying asset (e.g., swaps, futures, options)
- Foreign Debt: borrowing from overseas with obligation to pay interest and repay principal
- Debt metrics
- Gross foreign debt: total amount Australians borrow from non-residents
- Net foreign debt: gross foreign debt − total lending by Australians to non-residents
- Example: if government, businesses, and individuals borrow 2 ext{ trillion} from overseas, gross foreign debt = 2 ext{ trillion}
- If Australians have lent 0.5 ext{ trillion} to foreigners, net foreign debt = 2 - 0.5 = 1.5 ext{ trillion}
- Page 3
- Types of Foreign Debt and Equity
- Foreign Debt by sector
- Public sector debt (external sovereign debt): money owed by government to overseas parties; ~40% of net foreign debt
- Private sector debt: money owed by financial institutions and other businesses to overseas parties; ~60% of net foreign debt
- Foreign Equity concepts
- Total Foreign Equity: total value of Australia’s domestic assets owned by foreigners
- Net Foreign Equity: value of foreign-owned domestic assets minus value of Australian assets owned overseas
- Foreign Equity types
- Foreign direct investment (FDI) in equity: complete takeover or substantial share purchase with management control (≥ 10% of asset)
- Portfolio Investment: investment in stocks/bonds/assets without control (< 10% of asset)
- Page 4
- Foreign Liabilities and Assets; Savings-Investment Gap
- Foreign Liabilities: Australia’s total financial obligations to foreigners (foreign debt + foreign equity)
- Decomposition reminders
- Foreign debt split: amount borrowed from foreigners vs. amount Australians lend to foreigners
- Foreign equity split: value of domestic assets owned by foreigners vs. overseas assets owned by Australians
- Total Foreign Liabilities vs Total Foreign Assets
- Total Foreign Liabilities = amount borrowed from foreigners + value of domestic assets owned by foreigners (capital inflow)
- Total Foreign Assets = amount Australians lend to foreigners + value of overseas assets owned by Australians (capital outflow)
- Net Foreign Liabilities: Total Foreign Liabilities − Total Foreign Assets
- Net Foreign Liabilities = Net Foreign Debt + Net Foreign Equity
- Foreign Investment and the savings-investment gap
- The Australian Government has encouraged foreign investment to supplement the domestic savings pool
- Australia’s low domestic savings partly due to small population
- Page 5
- Trade and Financial Flows; Balance of Payments (BOP)
- Goods balance: goods credits − goods debits
- Service balance: service credits − service debits
- Balance of Payments (BOP): records all transactions between residents and the rest of the world over a period; shows money inflows and outflows
- Credits vs Debits
- Credits = inflows (payments received)
- Debits = outflows (payments made)
- BOP accounts structure
- Current account (CA)
- Capital and Financial Account (KAFA)
- Note: BOP is a recording of transactions; requires accuracy and consistency
- Page 6
- Current Account Components: NPI, NSI
- Net Primary Income (NPI)
- Records income flows from factors of production (land, labour, capital, entrepreneurship)
- Related to earned income and investment returns
- Credits: income from lending to overseas (interest received); income from Australian-owned assets overseas (rent, profits, dividends)
- Debits: borrowing from overseas (interest payments); income from foreign-owned assets in Australia (rent, profits, dividends paid to foreigners)
- Net Primary Income: Credits − Debits (usually a deficit, i.e., outflows exceed inflows)
- Net Secondary Income (NSI)
- Records one-sided, unearned transfers with no corresponding goods/services provided
- Examples: government grants, worker remittances, insurance claims, foreign aid for non-capital items
- Page 7
- Capital and Financial Account (KAFA)
- KAFA records reversible transactions between Australia and the rest of the world; typically in surplus
- KAFA categories
- Capital account: transfers of non-produced, non-financial assets (intellectual property rights like patents, copyrights, trademarks, royalties, franchises)
- Example: Australian company purchasing rights to operate a US Subway outlet in Australia is a debit on the capital account (outflow)
- Foreign aid can be recorded here as foreign infrastructure/capital aid (specific aid)
- Financial account: financial transactions (borrowing/lending, asset purchases) that are reversible
- Page 8
- Balancing the Balance of Payments
- The total balance of payments should sum to zero in the long run
- In practice, measurement errors and omissions can cause discrepancies
- Errors and Omissions: a CAFA subcomponent used to balance the accounts
- Why BOP sums to zero
- CAD increases require higher KAFA surplus and vice versa (inverse relationship)
- Floating exchange rate context
- Floating dollar helps restore BOP balance by adjusting demand/supply for AUD
- Page 9
- Market for the Australian Dollar (AUD)
- Supply and demand in forex market are derived from cross-border trade and investment
- Demand for AUD is derived from foreigners needing AUD to buy Australian goods/services/assets; and from returns like rents/dividends/interest paid to Australians
- For supply of AUD, Australians supply AUD to buy foreign currency when purchasing imports or investing overseas
- Notation: x-axis = quantity of AUD; y-axis = price (exchange rate in terms of another currency, e.g., USD)
- Page 10
- Floating Exchange Rate and CAKAFA Relationship
- When Australians borrow from overseas (outside money), KAFA records inflows (credit) and primary income records interest payments as debits
- Principal repayments appear as KAFA debits; this interacts with CA via net primary income movements
- Foreign investment in Australia (FDI/portfolio) is KAFA credit; returns (rent/dividends/profits) are debited in the current account as part of NPI
- Consequences
- Increases in foreign inflows raise KAFA surplus but can widen the current account deficit (CAD) due to greater returns (NPI) payable
- CAD growth necessitates more KAFA inflows, potentially creating a debt-trap cycle
- Page 11
- Debt Trap Cycle and Competitiveness
- Debt trap cycle concept
- Australia’s low savings rates lead to reliance on overseas investment to fund investment and growth
- Inflows boost KAFA surplus but increase interest costs on foreign liabilities, worsening CAD
- Higher CAD requires more foreign borrowing to service debt, raising foreign debt further
- Impact of international competitiveness on the Balance of Trade (BOGS)
- International competitiveness = ability to compete with other countries in exports and imports
- Factors influencing Australia’s international competitiveness
- Inflation: high domestic prices raise production costs, reducing competitiveness
- Wages: higher wages raise prices, reducing competitiveness
- High labour costs: increase imports and reduce exports
- Productivity: higher productivity improves competitiveness
- Exchange rate value: a weaker AUD improves competitiveness; a stronger AUD reduces it
- Page 12
- Trends in Net Primary Income (NPI)
- NPI deficit is typically the largest component of the CA deficit
- Resource/commodity booms attract foreign investment, increasing repayments overseas
- Higher TOT due to commodity price booms attracts more foreign investment ( profitable sectors)
- Lower global interest rates reduce interest payments and improve NPI position
- Savings–Investment gap necessitates foreign investment; returns on these investments are paid as primary income
- Note: “Savings-Investment Gap” is a recurrent theme affecting CA dynamics
- Page 13
- Impacts of International Borrowing and Foreign Investment
- International borrowing affects NPI via higher future debt service obligations
- When Australians borrow, the initial borrowing is a KAFA credit; interest payments are a NPI debit
- Increase in foreign debt raises foreign liabilities and servicing obligations (interest payments)
- Foreign investment (FDI/portfolio) improves competitiveness and growth but also generates returns payable in the current account (NPI debited)
- Page 14
- Measuring CAD Sustainability and Related Impacts
- How to measure the sustainability of the CAD
- Quantitative: CAD as % of GDP; a CAD above 4% of GDP is considered high and potentially unsustainable
- Qualitative: ability to attract foreign investment; ability to service foreign liabilities; sustained economic growth
- Effects of a high CAD
- Growth in foreign liabilities: higher borrowings and foreign equity needs to finance CAD and growth
- Increased servicing costs: interest on debt and returns on equity (dividends)
- Constraint on future growth: CAD can constrain growth via the national accounts equation: ext{GDP}=C+I+G+(X-M); higher imports reduce net exports and GDP growth
- More volatile exchange rates due to investor confidence shifts and risk perceptions
- Contractionary policies may be used to reduce CAD, potentially lowering growth
- Loss of investor confidence can hurt credit rating and investment
- Pitchford Thesis – Consenting Adults
- CAD is not inherently problematic if driven by private sector savings/investment decisions
- Private sector borrowing can expand productive capacity, boost growth, create jobs
- Majority of foreign debt in Australia is private sector borrowing, not government borrowing
- Page 15
- Exchange Rates: Basics
- Exchange rate definition: price of 1 currency in terms of another currency or a basket of currencies
- Foreign exchange market (forex): market where currencies are bought and sold
- Bilateral rates: currency value against one other currency (e.g., AUD/USD)
- Quotations
- Indirect method (common in media): how much foreign currency 1 AUD can buy (e.g., 1 AUD = 0.68 USD)
- Direct method: how many AUD per unit of foreign currency (e.g., how many AUD for 1 USD)
- Converting indirect to direct involves reciprocal relationships
- Page 16
- Measuring and Regimes for Exchange Rates
- Bilateral rates may misrepresent currency performance; compare across multiple currencies or use a Trade-Weighted Index (TWI)
- Trade Weighted Index (TWI): performance of the AUD against major trading partners’ currencies; better measure of competitiveness
- Exchange rate regimes
- Floating/flexible (clean): no government intervention; market forces determine rate
- Floating/flexible (dirty): occasional short-term central bank intervention to stabilize fluctuations
- Managed exchange rate: central bank intervenes when currency moves outside a target band
- Fixed/pegged: currency fixed to another currency or basket; central bank must intervene continuously to maintain the peg
- AUD supply in forex market
- AUD is supplied (sold) to buy foreign currency to pay for imports
- Also supplied when sending income abroad (e.g., returning dividends); investors convert AUD to foreign currency for overseas investments
- Page 17
- AUD Demand and Appreciation/Depreciation Dynamics
- AUD demand in forex market comes from: obtaining Australian goods/services, asset payments (rents, profits, dividends), and foreign investment in Australia
- If demand for AUD increases, AUD appreciates (price rises: e.g., from 0.68 to 0.75 per USD) because more foreigners want AUD
- Appreciation effects: reduces international competitiveness (exports become more expensive; imports cheaper)
- If demand for AUD decreases, AUD depreciates (price falls: e.g., from 0.75 to 0.62 per USD) because fewer want AUD
- Page 18
- Floating Exchange Rate: Clean vs Dirty; Advantages/Disadvantages
- Clean float: no government intervention; rate determined purely by market forces
- Dirty float: occasional short-term central bank intervention to reduce fluctuations
- Fixed/pegged systems involve continuous government intervention to maintain a target price
- Consequences of floating rates
- Reduces need for large foreign exchange reserves
- Risks include speculative bubbles and volatility in currency values
- Page 19
- Direct vs Indirect Intervention by RBA; Revaluation and Devaluation
- Direct intervention (unsterilized vs sterilized)
- Unsterilized: direct change in exchange rate by buying/selling foreign exchange; affects money supply and can move short-term rates
- Sterilized: offset liquidity effects of direct intervention by selling/buying domestic government securities to keep money supply unchanged; preserves the target exchange rate without changing the cash rate
- Revaluation: central bank increases the value of a fixed currency; may require intervention (buy AUD with foreign currency)
- Devaluation: central bank lowers the value of a fixed currency; may require intervention (sell AUD for foreign currency)
- ESAs (Exchange Settlement Accounts): banks hold reserves with the central bank; interventions affect liquidity and thus short-term rates
- Page 20
- Managed and Policy Implications of Exchange Rate Management
- Managing exchange rate fluctuations can reduce volatility and provide stability for businesses and investors
- Market expectations and speculation can cause overshooting or undershooting; central banks may intervene to keep outcomes within target bands
- Potential conflicts with other policy objectives (e.g., inflation control) when adjusting currency values
- Page 21
- Market for Australian Dollars – Summary of Mechanisms
- Demand for AUD is derived from: foreigners needing AUD for imports/transactions and for returns on Australian assets
- Supply of AUD is derived from: Australians needing foreign currencies for imports/investment and for repatriating income
- Theory summary: intersection of demand and supply determines the equilibrium exchange rate; quotations usually in terms of another currency or a basket (TWI)
- Indirect method example: 1 AUD buys 0.68 USD; shifts in demand/supply move the rate (appreciation if demand rises; depreciation if supply rises)
- Page 22
- Factors Influencing Demand for Australian Dollars (Part 1)
- Demand for Australian exports increases demand for AUD (foreign buyers convert to AUD)
- Higher TOT makes exports more expensive for foreigners, potentially influencing demand for AUD accordingly
- Page 23
- Continuing Demand Factors for AUD
- Relative rates of domestic and world economic growth: stronger global growth increases demand for Australian exports, raising demand for AUD
- Terms of Trade (TOT): higher export prices relative to import prices increase demand for AUD
- Demand for Australian assets (shares, real estate, government bonds, currency): investors convert to AUD to buy these assets, increasing demand for AUD (appreciation)
- Australian interest rate differential: higher domestic rates attract foreign capital, causing appreciation; lower rates reduce demand for AUD
- Page 24
- Further Demand/Inflation Dynamics; Inflation and Expectations
- Inflation: higher inflation reduces international competitiveness; exporters pass costs to prices, reducing demand for AUD (depreciation); lower inflation can improve competitiveness and demand for AUD (appreciation)
- Exchange rate expectations: speculation drives demand; expected appreciation boosts AUD; expected depreciation reduces demand
- Income repatriation: when Australians receive income from foreign assets, they may demand AUD to repatriate (affecting demand in forex market)
- Page 25
- Factors Influencing Supply of the AUD (Part 2)
- Demand for foreign imports by Australians increases AUD supply (to buy foreign currency)
- Australian demand for foreign assets (FDI/portfolio) increases AUD supply when converting to foreign currency
- Shifts in supply depend on relative interest rates and expectations; higher demand for foreign assets increases AUD supply (depreciation), lower demand can cause appreciation
- Page 26
- Additional Determinants of AUD Supply and Demand
- Relative interest rate differential: lower Australian rates encourage capital outflows and increase AUD supply; higher rates attract inflows and reduce supply (or increase demand for AUD)
- Exchange rate expectations: expected depreciation leads to higher current supply as investors move assets; expected appreciation can reduce supply
- Relative growth: higher domestic vs. global growth can expand imports, increasing AUD supply; strong growth may also attract foreign investment (unclear net effect)
- Transfer of income: when foreigners buy Australian assets, remitted income can be repatriated, affecting AUD supply/demand
- Page 27
- Link to the Balance of Payments (BOP)
- How demand/supply of AUD tie to BOP components
- Demand factors and BOP linkages
- Demand for Australian exports increases AUD demand, boosting CA/BOGS credits and AUD value (appreciation)
- Demand for Australian assets by foreigners (e.g., BHP shares) increases AUD demand via KAFA/portfolio investment, causing appreciation
- Supply factors and BOP linkages
- Demand for foreign imports reduces AUD demand for AUD (increases supply), causing depreciation
- Demand for Australian assets by residents abroad increases AUD supply as they convert to foreign currency (debit on KAFA, depreciation)
- Other transactions on the BOP (e.g., franchise purchases, dividend payments) affect the CA/KAFA balance and AUD exchange rate
- Page 28
- Why does the RBA Intervene?
- The AUD value is not targeted as a specific objective by the RBA, but intervention occurs to manage volatility and align with macro goals
- RBA interventions historically aimed at smoothing volatility after the 1983 float
- Objectives include preventing excessive depreciation (which raises import prices and inflation) and excessive appreciation (which raises export prices and may reduce growth)
- Indirect Intervention (via policy tools)
- The RBA can influence the currency without changing the cash rate via monetary policy adjustments or macroeconomic policy stances
- Jawboning: public statements by officials to influence expectations and market behavior
- Macroeconomic policy adjustments to influence demand for imports and overall growth
- Unsterilized vs Sterilized Interventions
- Unsterilized intervention: direct FX market action changes money supply and can move short-term rates
- Sterilized intervention: FX market action paired with offsetting open-market operations to keep the cash rate unchanged
- The RBA can use sterilized intervention to influence the exchange rate without altering the monetary policy stance
- Page 29
- Mechanisms of FX Market Intervention (Detailed)
- If the RBA wants a weaker AUD: sell AUD in FX market (buy foreign currency); AUD supply increases; banks’ ESAs rise; cash in money market increases; short-term rates may fall
- If the RBA wants a stronger AUD: buy AUD in FX market (sell foreign currency); AUD demand rises; ESAs decrease; money market liquidity tightens; short-term rates may rise
- Direct FX operations and ESAs link to monetary conditions
- Page 30
- Sterilized Intervention (Continuing)
- After FX intervention, the RBA may conduct sterilized operations by selling government securities to shrink the money supply back to its original level, leaving the cash rate unchanged
- Page 31
- Practical Outcomes of FX Intervention
- Increases or decreases in exchange rate can impact inflation, competitiveness, and growth depending on the direction of change
- FX interventions can be a tool to stabilize macroeconomic outcomes without triggering unwanted monetary tightening or loosening
- Page 32
- Changes in Exchange Rates – Appreciation and Depreciation
- Appreciation: rise in value of a currency; caused by increased demand or reduced supply; example: rate moves from $0.68 to $0.75
- Depreciation: fall in value of a currency; caused by increased supply or decreased demand; example: rate moves from $0.75 to $0.68
- Page 33
- Free Trade and Protection – Policy History
- Australia’s move from a highly protected economy to a liberal trading regime over decades
- Tariffs declined gradually since the 1960s; non-tariff barriers (quotas, subsidies) reduced over time
- Timeline highlights
- 1901: Protection policies to develop infant manufacturing industries (small population, low production)
- 1930s: Protection intensified during the Great Depression (British Preferential tariff 35%; General tariff >60% for non-Commonwealth countries)
- 1967: Joined GATT (precursor to WTO) and began opening up
- 1970–71: Effective protection in manufacturing ~35%; agricultural ~25%
- 1973: Whitlam government cut across-the-board tariffs by 25% to expose markets to competition
- 1983: First FTA with New Zealand
- 1988: Hawke government tariff reductions; manufacturing protection fell from ~15% (1989) to ~10% (1994) with some exemptions (cars, textiles)
- 1991: Building a Competitive Australia (policy statement)
- 1995: WTO replaces GATT
- 2000: Tariffs on passenger motor vehicles gradually reduced
- Page 34
- Rationale Behind Policies
- Benefits of specialization and economies of scale; lower costs, higher productivity
- Benefits to consumers: lower prices, more choices
- Supports higher living standards; longer-term employment prospects
- Encourages competition, innovation, and efficiency (allocative and dynamic)
- Promotes GDP growth and export expansion; access to new markets
- Exposes local industries to global competition; aims to improve technical, allocative and dynamic efficiency
- Process is slow and gradual; structural adjustments managed by government to minimize unemployment costs
- Page 35
- Current Policies and Trade Aid
- Free Trade Agreements (FTAs): pursuing WTO-consistent, high-quality bilateral/multilateral FTAs that offer net benefits; example: Australia–Hong Kong FTA effective 17 January 2020; pursuing EU FTA
- APEC membership: forum to discuss trade/policy; reduce impediments to business; promote open trade/investment
- Austrade and export market development grants: provide financial assistance, loans, bonds, guarantees to exporters
- Budgetary assistance: tax concessions and subsidies across sectors (mining, manufacturing, services, agriculture)
- Tariff assistance: targeted subsidies for farmers and manufacturing
- Anti-Dumping Commission: addresses dumping practices
- Page 36
- Australia’s FTAs – ASEAN-led and CPTPP Context
- ASEAN+New Zealand Free Trade Agreement (AANZFTA): multilateral framework with ASEAN bloc; in force since 2010; key members include Australia, New Zealand, Brunei, Burma, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Vietnam; tariff reductions, supply-chain opportunities, investment certainty
- CPTPP (Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership): 11 countries; about 495 million people; ~13.5% of global merchandise trade; benefits include reduced tariffs, easier market entry, streamlined customs, growth opportunities
- Bilateral FTA (CHAFTA) with China: tariff reductions/elimination on agricultural products (dairy, beef, wine) and other goods; expanded access to Chinese market; examples of export growth in beef, wine, dairy; reforms for services and investment, including healthcare and professional services
- Page 37
- Australia’s Bilateral FTA with Korea (KAFTA)
- KAFTA entered into force 12 December 2014
- Benefits include: 99%+ of Australian goods exports to Korea eligible for duty-free or favorable access; elimination of important tariffs (e.g., 40% tariff on beef in 2028)
- Reductions in market access barriers for Australian law firms to operate in Korea
- Negative Impacts of Free Trade on Australians
- Structural unemployment due to industry restructuring; short-term job losses for low-skilled workers; need for retraining and upskilling
- Real wages may not rise quickly if demand for labor is weak in affected sectors
- Page 38
- Positive Impacts of Free Trade on Australians
- Workers who adapt quickly gain opportunities in services and high-skilled manufacturing; potential for higher productivity and growth
- Consumers benefit from lower prices and greater product variety; improved quality from competition; better customer service
- Businesses can expand to export markets; lower input costs due to tariff reductions; enhanced competitiveness
- Government Perspectives on Free Trade (Negative)
- Potential loss of tariff revenue; higher structural adjustment costs (unemployment benefits, retraining)
- Political costs: policies may be unpopular and contested by voters in the short term
- Possible negative impacts on the BOGS and CAD if inputs rise and competitiveness worsens
- Page 39
- Government Perspectives on Free Trade (Positive)
- Potential reduction in government spending due to lower tariffs and subsidies
- Increased efficiency as resources shift to competitive industries; economies benefit from innovation and productivity gains
- Greater export diversification; buffers against external shocks; potential reduction in imported inflation due to tariff reductions
- Free trade supports macro policy flexibility by stabilizing inflation and reducing the need for tight monetary policy