Focus on Statistical Discrimination
Also includes extensions and tests
The lecture is being recorded for review purposes.
Key Sources: Arrow (1972) and Phelps (1972)
Uncertainty regarding individual productivity leads employers to rely on perceived average productivity based on group characteristics.
Group characteristics are used as proxies due to limited information on individual applicants.
Behavioral traits (e.g., aggression, competitiveness)
Job commitment (e.g., assumptions about pregnant women's reliability)
Health concerns (e.g., perceptions regarding gay men and HIV)
An employer might discriminate against certain groups if they believe these groups are generally less qualified based solely on limited perceptions—specifically, using race or gender as proxies for productivity.
Film Highlight: "Up in the Air" clip used for illustrating statistical discrimination concepts.
Does not require an employer to hold racist or sexist views.
Decisions are rational responses to incomplete information.
With complete information, statistical discrimination does not occur; nonetheless, it remains a form of discrimination and is often illegal.
Definition: Higher perceived variance in productivity within a less familiar group, potentially leading to discrimination.
References Klumpp and Su (2013) as a key study discussing phenomena of educational and occupational bias against women due to perceived lower variance in human capital.
The differences in labor market outcomes often stem from the skills and qualifications that individuals bring to the market.
Investment insights can be influenced by expectations of how different individuals will be treated in job markets.
Statistical discrimination can be viewed as a solution to information asymmetry.
Some economists argue that it could be justified if it maximizes profits by treating individuals of the same expected productivity identically.
Statistical discrimination is illegal in several jurisdictions when it involves protected categories.
Example: Police racial profiling stems from statistical expectations but leads to unfair consequences for innocent individuals, highlighting the equity-efficiency trade-off.
Used to measure discrimination via matched testers from different demographic backgrounds applying for the same roles.
Focus on initial entry points; limited insights on later stages like promotions.
Investigated impact of blind auditions on female musicians in orchestras.
Found that blind auditions led to increased hiring of women, indicating bias removal.
Difficulty in discerning between taste-based and statistical discrimination due to the nature of blind auditions.
Resumes sent with racially distinct names to measure callback rates.
Concluded distinctively Black names received fewer callbacks despite similar qualifications.
Heckman (1998): Differences in variances among unobservable characteristics could bias results in studies of discrimination.
List (2004): Examined discrimination in the marketplace; minority sellers often received inferior offers.
Statistical discrimination remains a critical topic within the discourse on workplace equity and efficiency. Key studies provide evidence of its prevalence and impact across different sectors.