Chapter 9: Market Structures, Perfect Competition, Monopoly, and Things Between
All firms are too small to influence market in any way, hence there are multiple producers in the market
This means that no 1 firm can drive up or down the prices of the products in the market by influencing the output
Consumers on the other end can also not influence the prices by consuming more or less
All firms in the market produce almost the same product
No significant obstacles to the entry of new firms into, or the exit of existing firms out of, this industry
Since none of the firms can influence the prices, they go along with the prices which are set by the market and produce how much they want
Any firm which tries to increase the price even by a dollar would end up losing customers, due to as mentioned earlier about the production of standardized products
Consumers would not prefer buying expensive products if they can get it cheaper elsewhere
Since each firm’s output is such a small share of the total market supply, the demand for each firm’s output is perfectly elastic
They simply produce as much as they can at the going price hence a horizontal demand curve
Keep in mind that the horizontal demand curve is of individual producers, not the market demand curve
Maximizing economic profit is highest possible difference between total revenue and total economic cost
Any opportunity is seized where even if one extra dollar is being earned
If the maximum profit possible is actually zero, or even negative dollars, they accept this short-run outcome
Since prices can’t be altered, firms look to manipulate the output.
Imagine a carrot farmer operating in a perfectly competitive market, sales carrots for $11
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | Profit |
---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $0 | $16 | -$16 |
1 | $11 | $11 | $22 | -$11 |
2 | $11 | $22 | $27.50 | -$5.50 |
3 | $11 | $33 | $34 | -$1 |
4 | $11 | $44 | $42 | $2 |
5 | $11 | $55 | $53 | $2 |
6 | $11 | $66 | $65 | $1 |
As noticeable from the chart, total cost increases with increased production
Logically, the carrot farmer would grow 5 bushels of carrots to generate more economic profit
When there are two quantities that produce the same amount of profit, like 4 and 5 bushels, we select the larger of the two quantities
Only decision to be made by perfectly competitive firm is to choose the optimal level of output.
1. Choose the level of output where MR = MC
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | Profit | Marginal revenue | Marginal cost |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $0 | $16 | -$16 | ||
1 | $11 | $11 | $22 | -$11 | $11 | $6 |
2 | $11 | $22 | $27.50 | -$5.50 | $11 | $5.50 |
3 | $11 | $33 | $34 | -$1 | $11 | $6.50 |
4 | $11 | $44 | $42 | $2 | $11 | $8 |
5 | $11 | $55 | $53 | $2 | $11 | $11 |
6 | $11 | $66 | $65 | $1 | $11 | $12 |
Since MR=MC at 5 bushels of carrot, the farmer would grow that level
Price = Marginal revenue in perfectly competitive market structures
This is because Farmers can sell as much as they want at the market price hence earn the same amount of marginal revenue
Price is also equivalent to average revenue (AR), or total revenue per unit
Profit = qe x (P-ATC)
The term (P - ATC) is the per-unit difference between what the firms receives from the sale of each unit and the average cost of producing it, or profit per unit
Multiply this per-unit profit by the number of units (qe) produced, you have total profit
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total cost | Average total cost | (P-ATC) | Profit |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $16 | $16 | -$16 | |
1 | $11 | $22 | $22 | -$11 | -$11 |
2 | $11 | $27.50 | $27.50 | -$2.75 | -$5.50 |
3 | $11 | $34 | $34 | -$.33 | -$1 |
4 | $11 | $42 | $42 | $.50 | $2 |
5 | $11 | $53 | $53 | $.40 | $2 |
6 | $11 | $65 | $65 | $.17 | $1 |
Never leave this level of output (qe)or bad things happen
We have positive economic profits of $2 if we produce at qe
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | profit | Marginal revenue | marginal cost |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $6.50 | $0 | $16 | -$16 | ||
1 | $6.50 | $6.50 | $22 | -$15.50 | $6.50 | $6 |
2 | $6.50 | $13 | $27.50 | -$14.50 | $6.50 | $5.5 |
3 | $6.50 | $19.50 | $34 | -$14.50 | $6.50 | $6.5 |
4 | $6.50 | $26 | $42 | -$16 | $6.50 | $8 |
5 | $6.50 | $32.50 | $53 | -$20.50 | $6.50 | $11 |
6 | $6.50 | $39 | $65 | -$26 | $6.50 | $12 |
MR=MC at 3 bushels now, however the carrot farmer would now face economic losses instead
At this point however, the farmer is able to minimize losses the most at this level
This becomes the loss minimizing level for him
Find qe where P = MR = MC. Once you have found qe, never leave it
Find ATC vertically at qe. If you move downward, π > 0. If you move upward, π < 0
Move horizontally from ATC to the y-axis to complete the rectangle, and clearly label it as positive or negative
If firms are incurring losses, they must decide whether it is economically rational to operate at all
Decision to shut down, or produce zero, in the short run is sometimes the optimal strategy
Total revenue is generated
Total variable cost is incurred (fixed cost is incurred irrespective of output)
If the firm is able to at least meet its total variable cost irrespective of fixed cost, it continues to operate under losses
However if the situation is dire and they are unable to cover their TVC, the firms best choice if to shutdown operation
This strategy would prevent firms from incurring more losses and only take the fixed cost as their losses
If TR ≥ TVC, the firm produces qe where MR = MC.
If TR < TVC, the firm shuts down and q = 0
If P ≥ AVC, the firm produces qe where MR = MC.
If P < AVC, the firm shuts down and q = 0
PH is the highest price. At qh, the firm earns enough total revenue to cover all costs (π > 0)
PM is the middle price. At qm, the firm’s TR exceeds TVC but only covers part of the TFC. π < 0.
PD is the shutdown price. At qd, the firm’s TR just covers TVC and the firm is at the shutdown point. If price falls any lower, the firm does not produce.
PL is the lowest price. At q1, the firm’s TR cannot even cover TVC, and so the firm shuts down, producing q = 0. π = -TFC
If price increases, quantity supplied increases
If price decreases, quantity supplied decreases
When the price falls below the shutdown point (minimum of AVC) and the firm quickly decides to produce nothing
The MC curve above the shutdown point serves as the supply curve for each perfectly competitive firm.
The market supply curve is therefore the horizontal sum of all of the MC curves: S = S MC
Firms enter and leave a perfectly competitive market based on the level of profits being made or the incurring of losses
Since the market price is above ATC, the firms in the market are earning a short term profit
In the long run however, seeing the success of the firms in the market, more firms join in
As more firms join in, the supply gradually increases because of which the market price comes down
As the market price comes down, firms already in the market begin to make less and less profit until there is no profit at all
At the point where P = MR = MC = ATC, each carrot farmer is now breaking even with π = 0
This breakeven point is described as the long-run equilibrium
Market quantity increases and Individual producer output falls.
Economic profit subtracts the next best opportunity costs of your resources from total revenue
Accounting profit is simply total cost – total revenue
You are making a fair rate of return on your invested resources and you have no incentive to take them elsewhere
Since market price is below ATC, the firms in the market incur losses
In the long run, when firms continue to incur losses, most of them would begin to leave the market
As more firms leave, the supply would automatically cut short, raising the market price
Overtime, losses would be reduced further leading to breaking even point eventually
At the point where PLR = MR = MC = ATC, each remaining carrot farmer is now breaking even with π = 0
Market quantity decreases and Individual producer output rises.
All the assumptions made up till now rely on one more assumption which is that it’s a constant cost industry
When new firms enter markets, the demand for key resources increases which in return increases the cost that would be incurred to employ these
The cost curves for firms in the industry start to shift upward and this is known as increasing cost industry
Entry of new firms drives down the price of the output and increases the cost curves, so the profit is eliminated more quickly than with our constant cost industry
Fewer firms eventually enter and the new long-run price is higher than it is in a constant cost industry
A decreasing cost industry is one in which the entry of new firms decreases the price of key resources and causes the cost curves to shift downward
The entry of new firms lowers the price of the output and decreases the cost curves, it takes longer for the profit to be eliminated than in our constant cost industry
More firms can eventually enter this market, and the new long-run price is lower than it would be in a constant cost industry
When the short run | The firm produces where | Short-run economic profit are | In the long run | The long-run outcome is |
---|---|---|---|---|
P>ATC | MR=MC | + | Firms enter | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
P=ATC | MR=MC | zero, breakeven | no entry/exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
AVC < P < ATC | MR=MC | - (0<profit<-TFC) | firms exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
P < AVC | zero, shutdown | -(=TFC) | firms exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
A single producer
No firms in industry at all
No close substitutes
Since only one firm dominates, there aren’t any substitutes available
Barriers to entry
Very high barriers to entry which prevents competition and limits consumer choice
Market power
Combining all factors above, monopolist dominate the market with their power
A benefit of any sort, provided solely to one firm only
This could be in the form of suppose being the only firm allowed to market their ads or being the only firm, which the government has allowed to sell in the market
Intellectual properties such as patent or trademarks also help in formation of monopoly to an extent
Cost advantage which is received due to fall in average cost as firm grow big in size, in the long run
Extensive economies of scale by a firm lead to industry relying on them solely
Natural monopoly are where economies of scale are so extensive that it is less costly for one firm to supply the entire range of demand e.g. power plants
Control of major resources by one firm makes it very difficult for other firms to enter and produce in the market
Monopolist have to pay attention to law of demand
P | Q | TR | MR |
---|---|---|---|
7 | 0 | 0 | |
6 | 1 | 6 | 6 |
5 | 2 | 10 | 4 |
4 | 3 | 12 | 2 |
3 | 4 | 12 | 0 |
2 | 5 | 10 | -2 |
1 | 6 | 6 | -4 |
0 | 7 | 0 | -6 |
Price > marginal revenue because the monopolist must lower price to boost sales
Added revenue from selling one more unit is the price of the last unit less the sum of the price cuts that must be taken on all prior units of output
Demand is elastic above the midpoint of a linear demand curve, hence price decrease increases total revenue
Demand is inelastic below the midpoint, hence price decrease decreases total revenue
Total revenue is maximized at the midpoint and demand here is unit elastic
Monopolists would avoid the inelastic portion of the demand curve and produce somewhere left of the midpoint
As visible from the curve, marginal revenue is zero when total revenue is maximized
Further price cuts decrease total revenue, making marginal revenue negative
The firm must set output at the level where MR = MC. At this level of output (Qm), the monopolist sets the price (Pm) from the demand curve
Monopoly profits are due to the entry barrier, to last into the long run
Incase demand plummets or perhaps production costs increase, to the point where P < ATC and losses are incurred, monopolist would leave the market if situation continues
Allocative efficiency is achieved when the market produces a level of output where the marginal cost (MC) to society exactly equals the marginal benefit (P) received by society
Total welfare is maximized at that level and any movement from the output would result in deadweight losses
Productive efficiency is achieved if society has produced a level of output with the lowest possible cost
In perfect competition, allocative efficiency is achieved in the long run where P = MR = MC at Q
Productive efficiency is achieved because firms produce at minimum ATC, once entry or exit has occurred in the long term
Monopoly doesn’t have both of these
Monopolist produces at a quantity Qm where Pm > MR = MC
This indicates that monopolists purposely don’t produce more, even though demand is there
This is known as market failure
The monopoly output isn’t at point where ATC is minimized;
This explains why monopolist aren’t productively efficient
A profit earned by the monopolist is a transfer of consumer surplus from consumers to the firm
It is the selling of the same good at different prices to different consumers e.g. Airline companies use this strategy
Firm has price control
Firm is able to identify and separate groups of consumers e.g. high and low income consumers
Firm is able to prevent resale between consumers (make sure the next consumers doesn’t get to know about the discrimination)
This occurs when the firm is able to charge the maximum possible price from different consumers for the same product
Imagine a scenario where a shop has a system that displays the maximum price each of their customer entering could pay for that product
This maximum price is easily visible to the cashier only and not to the consumer
For each different consumer, the maximum price they could pay would vary and the cashier would charge them that exact maximum price they can afford
The demand curve and marginal revenue are now the same (P = MR) for this
No single equilibrium price, because each customer was charged a different price
The monopolist takes all of it as producer surplus since there isn’t any consumer surplus
Last unit sold is the one for which P = MC, this outcome is allocatively efficient
There aren’t countless number of firms like perfect competition but there are quite a few number of firms each with a little market share
This feature differs them from perfectly competitive firms
This allows them to set price above competition level
Few barriers and the greatest one perhaps is that of marketing to showcase your differentiated product
Just like in a monopoly, demand curve is downward sloping due to their differentiated product
Similar substitutes available to consumers makes demand quite elastic
the firm sets Qmc where MR = MC and sets the price from the demand curve
Since easy entry and exit are there, profits aren’t going to be there in the long run
New firms entry into industry causes the market share of all existing firms to fall
As the price begins to fall, the profit reduces
Monopolistically competitive firms typically engage in extensive advertising to slow down, and even reverse, declining market share
This however is a short term effect
In long-run monopolistic competition, the firm earns normal profit of 0
P > MR = MC, allocative efficiency is not achieved due to the differentiated products
Breakeven level is achieved but the firms aren’t running on minimum ATC, hence productive efficiency isn’t achieved too
Monopolistic competition output Qmc - output at minimum ATC = excess capacity
It involves producing at an output less than that which minimizes ATC, hence the assets of the firm are underutilized
Market is overpopulated with firms, each producing enough to break even in the long run, but so many firms means that each produces below full capacity
Distribution of market share in an industry is among few large firms only
Oligopoly has a combination of both kind of products
The action of one firm (price setting or advertising) is likely to affect the others and prompt a response
Sum up the market share of the top 4, or 8, or 12 firms and create a concentration ratio
If the top 4 firms have a combined ratio of 85% (this is not universally agreed value as some economist prefer even 40%), the market is considered to be oligopolistic
Imagine a case where a two-firm oligopoly (a duopoly) engages in a daily pricing decision
Each firm knows that if it sets a price higher than the rival’s, it loses sales
Likewise, if it sets a price below the rival’s, it steals sales
This non-collusive model of pricing is called the prisoner’s dilemma
A college professor suspects two students (Jack and Diane) of cheating on a take-home final exam, but she cannot prove the guilt with enough certainty to fail both students in the course or expel them from the school
The college professor comes up with the following agreement which he discusses with each student individually
Jack’s choice | |||
---|---|---|---|
Confess | Stay silent | ||
Confess | D: fail courseJ: fail course | D: gets BJ: expelled | |
Diane’s choice | Stay silent | D: expelled J: gets B | D: gets DJ: gets D |
From the above payoff matrix (chart above), it becomes clear that Dianna’s best strategy should be to confess
Whether jack confesses or not, Dianna would benefit the most in both scenarios by confessing
If Jack confesses, Dianna simply fails the course instead of getting expelled if she too confesses
If jack decides to stay silent, Dianna gets a better grade if she confesses
Confession hence becomes her dominant strategy
Outcome of the game is the Nash Equilibrium (if both confess)
In term of economics, if each player’s strategy maximizes his or her payoff, given the strategies used by the rival players, this is the Nash Equilibrium
This is a dilemma because if Jack and Diane could only agree to give the professor the silent treatment, they would both walk away with a D, which is better than failing the course or expulsion
Without such a binding agreement, cheating on the pact would be quite tempting, maybe even fairly predictable
Sloppy’s choice | |||
---|---|---|---|
burger only | Add hot dog | ||
Burgers only | $500, $300 | $400,$400 | |
Stinky’s choice | Add hot dog | $600, $200 | $500, $100 |
Suppose there are two hamburger stands in town, Stinky’s and Sloppy’s, and each firm sells what it considers to be the best burger in town
Both burger stands are considering a move to offer hot dogs on the menu, or they could do nothing and continue to offer only burgers
Stinky’s has a dominant strategy of adding hot dogs to the menu while sloppy doesn’t have any
Sloppy’s recognizes that Stinky’s is going to add hot dogs to the menu and will respond by maintaining a burgers-only menu
The Nash equilibrium combination of payoffs is $600 for Stinky’s and $200 for Sloppy’s
No alternative outcome that would, with prior collusion, increase profits for both firms and hence this isn’t a prisoner dilemma situation
Explicit collusive behavior between direct competitors is an illegal business practice but does occur in the form of tacit (understood collusion)
Two competitors over time figure out that repeated attempts to undercut the price of their rivals is counterproductive
Hence if both set the price high, both firms win
When one cheats on this “understanding,” the other inflicts punishment with a retaliatory price cut
Cartels are groups of firms that create a formal agreement not to compete with each other on the basis of price, production, or other competitive dimensions
Cartels are more organized forms of collusive oligopoly behavior
They collectively operate as a monopolist to maximize their joint profits
Each cartel member agrees to a limited level of output resulting in a higher cartel price
Joint profits are maximized and distributed to each member
Difficulty in arriving at a mutually acceptable agreement to restrict output
Punishment mechanism
cartel members have the incentive to cheat by producing more than their allotment
Entry of new firms
Entry of new firms lead to cartel’s losing their monopoly power and profit.
All firms are too small to influence market in any way, hence there are multiple producers in the market
This means that no 1 firm can drive up or down the prices of the products in the market by influencing the output
Consumers on the other end can also not influence the prices by consuming more or less
All firms in the market produce almost the same product
No significant obstacles to the entry of new firms into, or the exit of existing firms out of, this industry
Since none of the firms can influence the prices, they go along with the prices which are set by the market and produce how much they want
Any firm which tries to increase the price even by a dollar would end up losing customers, due to as mentioned earlier about the production of standardized products
Consumers would not prefer buying expensive products if they can get it cheaper elsewhere
Since each firm’s output is such a small share of the total market supply, the demand for each firm’s output is perfectly elastic
They simply produce as much as they can at the going price hence a horizontal demand curve
Keep in mind that the horizontal demand curve is of individual producers, not the market demand curve
Maximizing economic profit is highest possible difference between total revenue and total economic cost
Any opportunity is seized where even if one extra dollar is being earned
If the maximum profit possible is actually zero, or even negative dollars, they accept this short-run outcome
Since prices can’t be altered, firms look to manipulate the output.
Imagine a carrot farmer operating in a perfectly competitive market, sales carrots for $11
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | Profit |
---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $0 | $16 | -$16 |
1 | $11 | $11 | $22 | -$11 |
2 | $11 | $22 | $27.50 | -$5.50 |
3 | $11 | $33 | $34 | -$1 |
4 | $11 | $44 | $42 | $2 |
5 | $11 | $55 | $53 | $2 |
6 | $11 | $66 | $65 | $1 |
As noticeable from the chart, total cost increases with increased production
Logically, the carrot farmer would grow 5 bushels of carrots to generate more economic profit
When there are two quantities that produce the same amount of profit, like 4 and 5 bushels, we select the larger of the two quantities
Only decision to be made by perfectly competitive firm is to choose the optimal level of output.
1. Choose the level of output where MR = MC
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | Profit | Marginal revenue | Marginal cost |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $0 | $16 | -$16 | ||
1 | $11 | $11 | $22 | -$11 | $11 | $6 |
2 | $11 | $22 | $27.50 | -$5.50 | $11 | $5.50 |
3 | $11 | $33 | $34 | -$1 | $11 | $6.50 |
4 | $11 | $44 | $42 | $2 | $11 | $8 |
5 | $11 | $55 | $53 | $2 | $11 | $11 |
6 | $11 | $66 | $65 | $1 | $11 | $12 |
Since MR=MC at 5 bushels of carrot, the farmer would grow that level
Price = Marginal revenue in perfectly competitive market structures
This is because Farmers can sell as much as they want at the market price hence earn the same amount of marginal revenue
Price is also equivalent to average revenue (AR), or total revenue per unit
Profit = qe x (P-ATC)
The term (P - ATC) is the per-unit difference between what the firms receives from the sale of each unit and the average cost of producing it, or profit per unit
Multiply this per-unit profit by the number of units (qe) produced, you have total profit
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total cost | Average total cost | (P-ATC) | Profit |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $11 | $16 | $16 | -$16 | |
1 | $11 | $22 | $22 | -$11 | -$11 |
2 | $11 | $27.50 | $27.50 | -$2.75 | -$5.50 |
3 | $11 | $34 | $34 | -$.33 | -$1 |
4 | $11 | $42 | $42 | $.50 | $2 |
5 | $11 | $53 | $53 | $.40 | $2 |
6 | $11 | $65 | $65 | $.17 | $1 |
Never leave this level of output (qe)or bad things happen
We have positive economic profits of $2 if we produce at qe
Daily bushels of carrots (q) | Price (P) | Total revenue | Total cost | profit | Marginal revenue | marginal cost |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | $6.50 | $0 | $16 | -$16 | ||
1 | $6.50 | $6.50 | $22 | -$15.50 | $6.50 | $6 |
2 | $6.50 | $13 | $27.50 | -$14.50 | $6.50 | $5.5 |
3 | $6.50 | $19.50 | $34 | -$14.50 | $6.50 | $6.5 |
4 | $6.50 | $26 | $42 | -$16 | $6.50 | $8 |
5 | $6.50 | $32.50 | $53 | -$20.50 | $6.50 | $11 |
6 | $6.50 | $39 | $65 | -$26 | $6.50 | $12 |
MR=MC at 3 bushels now, however the carrot farmer would now face economic losses instead
At this point however, the farmer is able to minimize losses the most at this level
This becomes the loss minimizing level for him
Find qe where P = MR = MC. Once you have found qe, never leave it
Find ATC vertically at qe. If you move downward, π > 0. If you move upward, π < 0
Move horizontally from ATC to the y-axis to complete the rectangle, and clearly label it as positive or negative
If firms are incurring losses, they must decide whether it is economically rational to operate at all
Decision to shut down, or produce zero, in the short run is sometimes the optimal strategy
Total revenue is generated
Total variable cost is incurred (fixed cost is incurred irrespective of output)
If the firm is able to at least meet its total variable cost irrespective of fixed cost, it continues to operate under losses
However if the situation is dire and they are unable to cover their TVC, the firms best choice if to shutdown operation
This strategy would prevent firms from incurring more losses and only take the fixed cost as their losses
If TR ≥ TVC, the firm produces qe where MR = MC.
If TR < TVC, the firm shuts down and q = 0
If P ≥ AVC, the firm produces qe where MR = MC.
If P < AVC, the firm shuts down and q = 0
PH is the highest price. At qh, the firm earns enough total revenue to cover all costs (π > 0)
PM is the middle price. At qm, the firm’s TR exceeds TVC but only covers part of the TFC. π < 0.
PD is the shutdown price. At qd, the firm’s TR just covers TVC and the firm is at the shutdown point. If price falls any lower, the firm does not produce.
PL is the lowest price. At q1, the firm’s TR cannot even cover TVC, and so the firm shuts down, producing q = 0. π = -TFC
If price increases, quantity supplied increases
If price decreases, quantity supplied decreases
When the price falls below the shutdown point (minimum of AVC) and the firm quickly decides to produce nothing
The MC curve above the shutdown point serves as the supply curve for each perfectly competitive firm.
The market supply curve is therefore the horizontal sum of all of the MC curves: S = S MC
Firms enter and leave a perfectly competitive market based on the level of profits being made or the incurring of losses
Since the market price is above ATC, the firms in the market are earning a short term profit
In the long run however, seeing the success of the firms in the market, more firms join in
As more firms join in, the supply gradually increases because of which the market price comes down
As the market price comes down, firms already in the market begin to make less and less profit until there is no profit at all
At the point where P = MR = MC = ATC, each carrot farmer is now breaking even with π = 0
This breakeven point is described as the long-run equilibrium
Market quantity increases and Individual producer output falls.
Economic profit subtracts the next best opportunity costs of your resources from total revenue
Accounting profit is simply total cost – total revenue
You are making a fair rate of return on your invested resources and you have no incentive to take them elsewhere
Since market price is below ATC, the firms in the market incur losses
In the long run, when firms continue to incur losses, most of them would begin to leave the market
As more firms leave, the supply would automatically cut short, raising the market price
Overtime, losses would be reduced further leading to breaking even point eventually
At the point where PLR = MR = MC = ATC, each remaining carrot farmer is now breaking even with π = 0
Market quantity decreases and Individual producer output rises.
All the assumptions made up till now rely on one more assumption which is that it’s a constant cost industry
When new firms enter markets, the demand for key resources increases which in return increases the cost that would be incurred to employ these
The cost curves for firms in the industry start to shift upward and this is known as increasing cost industry
Entry of new firms drives down the price of the output and increases the cost curves, so the profit is eliminated more quickly than with our constant cost industry
Fewer firms eventually enter and the new long-run price is higher than it is in a constant cost industry
A decreasing cost industry is one in which the entry of new firms decreases the price of key resources and causes the cost curves to shift downward
The entry of new firms lowers the price of the output and decreases the cost curves, it takes longer for the profit to be eliminated than in our constant cost industry
More firms can eventually enter this market, and the new long-run price is lower than it would be in a constant cost industry
When the short run | The firm produces where | Short-run economic profit are | In the long run | The long-run outcome is |
---|---|---|---|---|
P>ATC | MR=MC | + | Firms enter | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
P=ATC | MR=MC | zero, breakeven | no entry/exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
AVC < P < ATC | MR=MC | - (0<profit<-TFC) | firms exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
P < AVC | zero, shutdown | -(=TFC) | firms exit | Plr = MR = MC = ATC and profit =0 |
A single producer
No firms in industry at all
No close substitutes
Since only one firm dominates, there aren’t any substitutes available
Barriers to entry
Very high barriers to entry which prevents competition and limits consumer choice
Market power
Combining all factors above, monopolist dominate the market with their power
A benefit of any sort, provided solely to one firm only
This could be in the form of suppose being the only firm allowed to market their ads or being the only firm, which the government has allowed to sell in the market
Intellectual properties such as patent or trademarks also help in formation of monopoly to an extent
Cost advantage which is received due to fall in average cost as firm grow big in size, in the long run
Extensive economies of scale by a firm lead to industry relying on them solely
Natural monopoly are where economies of scale are so extensive that it is less costly for one firm to supply the entire range of demand e.g. power plants
Control of major resources by one firm makes it very difficult for other firms to enter and produce in the market
Monopolist have to pay attention to law of demand
P | Q | TR | MR |
---|---|---|---|
7 | 0 | 0 | |
6 | 1 | 6 | 6 |
5 | 2 | 10 | 4 |
4 | 3 | 12 | 2 |
3 | 4 | 12 | 0 |
2 | 5 | 10 | -2 |
1 | 6 | 6 | -4 |
0 | 7 | 0 | -6 |
Price > marginal revenue because the monopolist must lower price to boost sales
Added revenue from selling one more unit is the price of the last unit less the sum of the price cuts that must be taken on all prior units of output
Demand is elastic above the midpoint of a linear demand curve, hence price decrease increases total revenue
Demand is inelastic below the midpoint, hence price decrease decreases total revenue
Total revenue is maximized at the midpoint and demand here is unit elastic
Monopolists would avoid the inelastic portion of the demand curve and produce somewhere left of the midpoint
As visible from the curve, marginal revenue is zero when total revenue is maximized
Further price cuts decrease total revenue, making marginal revenue negative
The firm must set output at the level where MR = MC. At this level of output (Qm), the monopolist sets the price (Pm) from the demand curve
Monopoly profits are due to the entry barrier, to last into the long run
Incase demand plummets or perhaps production costs increase, to the point where P < ATC and losses are incurred, monopolist would leave the market if situation continues
Allocative efficiency is achieved when the market produces a level of output where the marginal cost (MC) to society exactly equals the marginal benefit (P) received by society
Total welfare is maximized at that level and any movement from the output would result in deadweight losses
Productive efficiency is achieved if society has produced a level of output with the lowest possible cost
In perfect competition, allocative efficiency is achieved in the long run where P = MR = MC at Q
Productive efficiency is achieved because firms produce at minimum ATC, once entry or exit has occurred in the long term
Monopoly doesn’t have both of these
Monopolist produces at a quantity Qm where Pm > MR = MC
This indicates that monopolists purposely don’t produce more, even though demand is there
This is known as market failure
The monopoly output isn’t at point where ATC is minimized;
This explains why monopolist aren’t productively efficient
A profit earned by the monopolist is a transfer of consumer surplus from consumers to the firm
It is the selling of the same good at different prices to different consumers e.g. Airline companies use this strategy
Firm has price control
Firm is able to identify and separate groups of consumers e.g. high and low income consumers
Firm is able to prevent resale between consumers (make sure the next consumers doesn’t get to know about the discrimination)
This occurs when the firm is able to charge the maximum possible price from different consumers for the same product
Imagine a scenario where a shop has a system that displays the maximum price each of their customer entering could pay for that product
This maximum price is easily visible to the cashier only and not to the consumer
For each different consumer, the maximum price they could pay would vary and the cashier would charge them that exact maximum price they can afford
The demand curve and marginal revenue are now the same (P = MR) for this
No single equilibrium price, because each customer was charged a different price
The monopolist takes all of it as producer surplus since there isn’t any consumer surplus
Last unit sold is the one for which P = MC, this outcome is allocatively efficient
There aren’t countless number of firms like perfect competition but there are quite a few number of firms each with a little market share
This feature differs them from perfectly competitive firms
This allows them to set price above competition level
Few barriers and the greatest one perhaps is that of marketing to showcase your differentiated product
Just like in a monopoly, demand curve is downward sloping due to their differentiated product
Similar substitutes available to consumers makes demand quite elastic
the firm sets Qmc where MR = MC and sets the price from the demand curve
Since easy entry and exit are there, profits aren’t going to be there in the long run
New firms entry into industry causes the market share of all existing firms to fall
As the price begins to fall, the profit reduces
Monopolistically competitive firms typically engage in extensive advertising to slow down, and even reverse, declining market share
This however is a short term effect
In long-run monopolistic competition, the firm earns normal profit of 0
P > MR = MC, allocative efficiency is not achieved due to the differentiated products
Breakeven level is achieved but the firms aren’t running on minimum ATC, hence productive efficiency isn’t achieved too
Monopolistic competition output Qmc - output at minimum ATC = excess capacity
It involves producing at an output less than that which minimizes ATC, hence the assets of the firm are underutilized
Market is overpopulated with firms, each producing enough to break even in the long run, but so many firms means that each produces below full capacity
Distribution of market share in an industry is among few large firms only
Oligopoly has a combination of both kind of products
The action of one firm (price setting or advertising) is likely to affect the others and prompt a response
Sum up the market share of the top 4, or 8, or 12 firms and create a concentration ratio
If the top 4 firms have a combined ratio of 85% (this is not universally agreed value as some economist prefer even 40%), the market is considered to be oligopolistic
Imagine a case where a two-firm oligopoly (a duopoly) engages in a daily pricing decision
Each firm knows that if it sets a price higher than the rival’s, it loses sales
Likewise, if it sets a price below the rival’s, it steals sales
This non-collusive model of pricing is called the prisoner’s dilemma
A college professor suspects two students (Jack and Diane) of cheating on a take-home final exam, but she cannot prove the guilt with enough certainty to fail both students in the course or expel them from the school
The college professor comes up with the following agreement which he discusses with each student individually
Jack’s choice | |||
---|---|---|---|
Confess | Stay silent | ||
Confess | D: fail courseJ: fail course | D: gets BJ: expelled | |
Diane’s choice | Stay silent | D: expelled J: gets B | D: gets DJ: gets D |
From the above payoff matrix (chart above), it becomes clear that Dianna’s best strategy should be to confess
Whether jack confesses or not, Dianna would benefit the most in both scenarios by confessing
If Jack confesses, Dianna simply fails the course instead of getting expelled if she too confesses
If jack decides to stay silent, Dianna gets a better grade if she confesses
Confession hence becomes her dominant strategy
Outcome of the game is the Nash Equilibrium (if both confess)
In term of economics, if each player’s strategy maximizes his or her payoff, given the strategies used by the rival players, this is the Nash Equilibrium
This is a dilemma because if Jack and Diane could only agree to give the professor the silent treatment, they would both walk away with a D, which is better than failing the course or expulsion
Without such a binding agreement, cheating on the pact would be quite tempting, maybe even fairly predictable
Sloppy’s choice | |||
---|---|---|---|
burger only | Add hot dog | ||
Burgers only | $500, $300 | $400,$400 | |
Stinky’s choice | Add hot dog | $600, $200 | $500, $100 |
Suppose there are two hamburger stands in town, Stinky’s and Sloppy’s, and each firm sells what it considers to be the best burger in town
Both burger stands are considering a move to offer hot dogs on the menu, or they could do nothing and continue to offer only burgers
Stinky’s has a dominant strategy of adding hot dogs to the menu while sloppy doesn’t have any
Sloppy’s recognizes that Stinky’s is going to add hot dogs to the menu and will respond by maintaining a burgers-only menu
The Nash equilibrium combination of payoffs is $600 for Stinky’s and $200 for Sloppy’s
No alternative outcome that would, with prior collusion, increase profits for both firms and hence this isn’t a prisoner dilemma situation
Explicit collusive behavior between direct competitors is an illegal business practice but does occur in the form of tacit (understood collusion)
Two competitors over time figure out that repeated attempts to undercut the price of their rivals is counterproductive
Hence if both set the price high, both firms win
When one cheats on this “understanding,” the other inflicts punishment with a retaliatory price cut
Cartels are groups of firms that create a formal agreement not to compete with each other on the basis of price, production, or other competitive dimensions
Cartels are more organized forms of collusive oligopoly behavior
They collectively operate as a monopolist to maximize their joint profits
Each cartel member agrees to a limited level of output resulting in a higher cartel price
Joint profits are maximized and distributed to each member
Difficulty in arriving at a mutually acceptable agreement to restrict output
Punishment mechanism
cartel members have the incentive to cheat by producing more than their allotment
Entry of new firms
Entry of new firms lead to cartel’s losing their monopoly power and profit.