Chapter 15 - Society and Economy Under the Old Regime in the Eighteenth Century
During the eighteenth century, newspapers flourished in the United Kingdom, and the advertisements they produced enhanced consumer desires. Britain's social system encourages citizens to emulate the lives of their social superiors. It appears that Britain was the first to build a fashion world that caused individuals to desire to amass commodities. In addition to local consumer demand, the British economy profited from demand from North American colonies.
Britain also has Europe's largest free-trade zone. The British possessed strong roads and rivers, and there were no internal tolls or other commercial restrictions. The country possessed abundant coal and iron ore resources. Its governmental framework was solid, and its citizens' property was completely safe. The strong banking and public credit systems that have been developed
Britain's taxation was high, but it was collected effectively and equitably, primarily through indirect taxes. Furthermore, British taxes were legalized by Parliament, with all socioeconomic levels and areas of the country paying the same taxes. Unlike on the Continent, there was no system of preferential tax exemptions.
Finally, by historical standards, British society was mobile. People with money or the ability to gain it might advance socially. The British aristocracy would accept persons with vast incomes into its ranks.
Even those who did not join the aristocracy may enjoy their money, gain social status, and wield political power. None of these causes foreshadowed Britain's march toward industrialism.
The manufacture of textiles for apparel was the industry that ushered in the Industrial Revolution and satisfied rising consumer demand. Textile manufacturing is a prime example of industrialism rising to meet the demands of an ever-expanding market for daily products. Furthermore, it demonstrates the startling reality that much of the initial industrial transformation occurred in the countryside rather than cities.
Although the economy of the eighteenth century was predominantly agrarian, industry was nevertheless prevalent in rural regions. The main unit of production was the peasant family living in a one- or two-room hut, rather than the factory. In the winter, the same peasants who tilled the field in the spring and summer spun thread or weaved fabrics.
The household textile manufacturing system was a fundamental part of this family economy, and it would remain so in Britain and on the Continent far into the nineteenth century. However, by the mid-eighteenth century, domestic manufacturing constraints had formed.
Cotton textile demand was expanding faster than output, particularly in the United Kingdom, which had a substantial domestic and North American market for these items. To accommodate customer demand for cotton textiles, inventors created some of the most renowned machinery of the early Industrial Revolution.
The steam engine, more than any other technology, enabled industrialisation to self-replicate and extend into one field of industry after another. For the first time in human history, this machine supplied a consistent and practically limitless supply of inanimate power. Unlike engines powered by water or wind, the steam engine, which was fuelled by coal, provided a portable source of industrial power that did not fail or weaken as the seasons changed.
Unlike human or animal power, the steam engine relied on inexhaustible mineral energy. Finally, the steam engine could be used in a variety of industrial and, eventually, transportation applications.
In the early eighteenth century, Thomas Newcomen (1663–1729) constructed the first workable steam engine.
Despite these issues, English miners employed the Newcomen machines to remove water from coal and tin mines. By the third quarter of the eighteenth century, about a hundred Newcomen machines were in use in England's mining areas.
James Watt, a Scottish engineer and machine manufacturer, began experimenting with a replica of a Newcomen machine at the University of Glasgow in the 1760s. He gradually realized that isolating the condenser from the piston and cylinder would result in significantly higher efficiency.
He patented his new invention in 1769, but turning his concept into a practical use proved challenging. His design necessitated the use of exact metallurgy.
Watt immediately found a business partner in Matthew Boulton (1728–1809), a prominent toy and button producer in Birmingham.
The production of high-quality iron has been fundamental to modern industrial progress. Iron is the primary component of all heavy industries as well as land and marine transportation.
The majority of productive machinery is likewise made of iron. British ironmakers produced fewer than 25,000 tons of iron per year in the early eighteenth century. Three things slowed manufacturing.
First, instead of coke, charcoal was used to smelt the ore. Charcoal, which is made from wood, was becoming rare as Britain's woods dwindled, and it does not burn at as high a temperature as coke, which is obtained from coal. Second, until the steam engine was perfected, furnaces could not reach high enough blasts. Finally, there was a scarcity of iron. The first two issues have been resolved.
During the eighteenth century, newspapers flourished in the United Kingdom, and the advertisements they produced enhanced consumer desires. Britain's social system encourages citizens to emulate the lives of their social superiors. It appears that Britain was the first to build a fashion world that caused individuals to desire to amass commodities. In addition to local consumer demand, the British economy profited from demand from North American colonies.
Britain also has Europe's largest free-trade zone. The British possessed strong roads and rivers, and there were no internal tolls or other commercial restrictions. The country possessed abundant coal and iron ore resources. Its governmental framework was solid, and its citizens' property was completely safe. The strong banking and public credit systems that have been developed
Britain's taxation was high, but it was collected effectively and equitably, primarily through indirect taxes. Furthermore, British taxes were legalized by Parliament, with all socioeconomic levels and areas of the country paying the same taxes. Unlike on the Continent, there was no system of preferential tax exemptions.
Finally, by historical standards, British society was mobile. People with money or the ability to gain it might advance socially. The British aristocracy would accept persons with vast incomes into its ranks.
Even those who did not join the aristocracy may enjoy their money, gain social status, and wield political power. None of these causes foreshadowed Britain's march toward industrialism.
The manufacture of textiles for apparel was the industry that ushered in the Industrial Revolution and satisfied rising consumer demand. Textile manufacturing is a prime example of industrialism rising to meet the demands of an ever-expanding market for daily products. Furthermore, it demonstrates the startling reality that much of the initial industrial transformation occurred in the countryside rather than cities.
Although the economy of the eighteenth century was predominantly agrarian, industry was nevertheless prevalent in rural regions. The main unit of production was the peasant family living in a one- or two-room hut, rather than the factory. In the winter, the same peasants who tilled the field in the spring and summer spun thread or weaved fabrics.
The household textile manufacturing system was a fundamental part of this family economy, and it would remain so in Britain and on the Continent far into the nineteenth century. However, by the mid-eighteenth century, domestic manufacturing constraints had formed.
Cotton textile demand was expanding faster than output, particularly in the United Kingdom, which had a substantial domestic and North American market for these items. To accommodate customer demand for cotton textiles, inventors created some of the most renowned machinery of the early Industrial Revolution.
The steam engine, more than any other technology, enabled industrialisation to self-replicate and extend into one field of industry after another. For the first time in human history, this machine supplied a consistent and practically limitless supply of inanimate power. Unlike engines powered by water or wind, the steam engine, which was fuelled by coal, provided a portable source of industrial power that did not fail or weaken as the seasons changed.
Unlike human or animal power, the steam engine relied on inexhaustible mineral energy. Finally, the steam engine could be used in a variety of industrial and, eventually, transportation applications.
In the early eighteenth century, Thomas Newcomen (1663–1729) constructed the first workable steam engine.
Despite these issues, English miners employed the Newcomen machines to remove water from coal and tin mines. By the third quarter of the eighteenth century, about a hundred Newcomen machines were in use in England's mining areas.
James Watt, a Scottish engineer and machine manufacturer, began experimenting with a replica of a Newcomen machine at the University of Glasgow in the 1760s. He gradually realized that isolating the condenser from the piston and cylinder would result in significantly higher efficiency.
He patented his new invention in 1769, but turning his concept into a practical use proved challenging. His design necessitated the use of exact metallurgy.
Watt immediately found a business partner in Matthew Boulton (1728–1809), a prominent toy and button producer in Birmingham.
The production of high-quality iron has been fundamental to modern industrial progress. Iron is the primary component of all heavy industries as well as land and marine transportation.
The majority of productive machinery is likewise made of iron. British ironmakers produced fewer than 25,000 tons of iron per year in the early eighteenth century. Three things slowed manufacturing.
First, instead of coke, charcoal was used to smelt the ore. Charcoal, which is made from wood, was becoming rare as Britain's woods dwindled, and it does not burn at as high a temperature as coke, which is obtained from coal. Second, until the steam engine was perfected, furnaces could not reach high enough blasts. Finally, there was a scarcity of iron. The first two issues have been resolved.