Economic Principles Review
Elasticities and Demand
Elasticities let us know how much demand (or supply) of a good changes in response to a price change.
Price Elasticity of Demand: Measures how quantity demanded reacts to a change in price, ignoring the minus sign.
Elastic Demand: If price elasticity > 1
Inelastic Demand: If price elasticity < 1
Income Elasticity
Income Elasticity of Demand: Measures how quantity demanded changes with income.
Greater than 1: income elastic, classified as a normal good.
Between 0 and 1: income inelastic, also a normal good.
Less than 0: classified as an inferior good.
Cross Price Elasticity
Cross (Price) Elasticity of Demand: Measures how the quantity demanded of one good reacts to price changes of another good.
Positive Cross Elasticity: Indicates substitute goods.
Negative Cross Elasticity: Indicates complementary goods.
Example Problem 1: Price Elasticity Calculation
Scenario: The price of Diet Coke rises from $0.75 to $1.25, and the quantity demanded falls from 180 to 140 units.
Price Elasticity Calculation: Explanatory Formula:
ext{Price Elasticity of Demand} = rac{ ext{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded}}{ ext{Percentage Change in Price}}
Example Problem 2: Income Elasticity Calculation
Scenario: Following a price increase, income increases from $100 to $200 and the consumption of Diet Coke rises to 340 units.
Calculate the income elasticity using:
ext{Income Elasticity} = rac{ ext{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded}}{ ext{Percentage Change in Income}}
Example Problem 3: Cross-Price Elasticity Calculation
Scenario: The quantity demanded of coffee increases from 50 to 70 units after a price change.
Calculate using:
ext{Cross-Price Elasticity} = rac{ ext{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded of Coffee}}{ ext{Percentage Change in Price of Another Good}}
Resource Allocation Methods
Different Methods of Allocating Scarce Resources
Allocation methods include:
Market price
Command
Majority rule
Contest
First-come, first-served
Lottery
Personal characteristics
Force
Market Price
Allocates scarce resources to those willing to pay.
People generally buy goods and services in markets.
The market effectively and efficiently allocates resources for most goods and services.
Command
Allocates resources according to orders from an authority.
Effective in organizations with clear lines of authority.
Ineffective for entire economies due to lack of flexibility.
Majority Rule
Allocates resources based on majority preferences.
Useful for societal decisions, e.g., tax rates.
Works better when self-interest is suppressed for overall efficiency.
Contest
Allocates resources among winners of competitions.
Examples: sporting events, awards.
Suitable when efforts are hard to monitor.
First-Come, First-Served
Allocates resources to those who arrive first.
Commonly used in casual dining and supermarket checkouts.
Best for resources that can serve one person at a time.
Lottery
Allocates resources through chance.
Used in state lotteries, casino games, and airport landing slots.
Effective when distinguishing between potential users is not feasible.
Personal Characteristics
Allocates resources based on attributes perceived as beneficial.
Examples: choosing marriage partners.
Can lead to unacceptable discrimination (e.g., racial or gender biases).
Force
Allocates resources through coercion or compulsion.
Historically significant in war and theft.
Can facilitate transfers of wealth to promote certain economic actions.
Demand, Value, and Willingness to Pay
Key Concepts
Value: Benefits received from a good.
Price: The monetary amount spent for goods or services.
The value of one more unit is defined as its Marginal Benefit.
Willingness to Pay: The maximum price a consumer is willing to pay for a good, which determines demand.
A demand curve acts as a marginal benefit curve.
Individual Demand and Market Demand
Individual Demand: Relationship between price and quantity demanded by an individual.
Market Demand: Relationship between price and quantity demanded by all buyers collectively.
Demand Examples
Consider Lisa and Nick:
Lisa buys 30 slices of pizza at $1 a slice.
Nick buys 10 slices at the same price.
Together, their market demand is for 40 slices.
Market Demand Curve
The market demand curve is represented as the horizontal sum of individual demand curves.
Graph illustrates the total quantity demanded at varying prices.
Consumer Surplus
Definition
Consumer Surplus: The difference between the benefit received from a good and the payment made for it.
Calculated as the marginal benefit minus the price across the quantity purchased.
Visual representation is the area under the demand curve and above the price, up to the quantity bought.
Example of Consumer Surplus Calculation
Scenario: Lisa at $1 per slice and a value on the 10th slice of $2.
Consumer surplus: 2 - 1 = 1 (from the 10th slice).
For Lisa buying 30 slices and Nick buying 10, their consumer surplus accumulates under the market demand curve.
Producer Surplus
Definition
Producer Surplus: The excess amount received from the sale over the cost of production.
Calculated as price received minus minimum supply price (marginal cost) for sold units.
Area representation is below market price and above the supply curve up to the quantity sold.
Example of Producer Surplus Calculation
Scenario: At $15 per pizza, if Maria is willing to produce the 50th pizza for $10, the surplus is 15 - 10 = 5 for that unit.
Market Efficiency and Failures
Competitive Equilibrium
Efficiency achieved when quantity demanded equals quantity supplied.
Marginal social benefit (MSB) aligns with marginal social cost (MSC) at equilibrium.
Produces maximum total surplus (sum of consumer and producer surplus).
Market Failures
Occurs when markets do not achieve efficient outcomes.
Reasons include:
Underproduction: Producing less than efficiency.
Overproduction: Producing more than efficiency.
Externalities: Costs or benefits affecting others outside the direct transaction.
Public Goods: Items that are non-excludable and non-rivalrous leading to free-riding issues.
Monopolies: Sole providers producing less than socially optimal amounts.
High Transaction Costs: Costs of market operation prevent efficient exchanges.
Alternatives to Market Outcomes
Non-market methods may sometimes allocate resources better.
Majority rule, command, and first-come-first-served can supplement market mechanisms, though with their own drawbacks.
Fairness and Economic Outcomes
Utilitarianism & Fairness
Utilitarianism: Philosophical idea that efficiency often hinges on equitable distribution of income.
Equal income distribution leads to maximized collective benefit.
Symmetry Principle
States that individuals in similar circumstances should be treated similarly in economic systems.
Encourages equality of opportunity over equality of outcome.
Water Pricing Example
Residential vs. agricultural pricing for water raised fairness questions and efficiency analysis of proposed adjustments.