Definition: Measures buyers’ responsiveness to price changes.
Types of Demand:
Elastic Demand: Sensitive to price changes; large change in quantity demanded.
Inelastic Demand: Insensitive to price changes; small change in quantity demanded.
Formula:
[ Ed = \frac{\text{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded}}{\text{Percentage Change in Price}} ]
Midpoint Formula:
Ensures consistent results:
[ Ed = \frac{\text{Change in Quantity}}{\text{Sum of Quantities}/2} \div \frac{\text{Change in Price}}{\text{Sum of Prices}/2} ]
Additional Notes:
Use percentages for a unit-free measure.
Eliminating the minus sign helps compare elasticities across products effectively.
Values Interpretation:
Ed > 1: Demand is elastic.
Ed = 1: Demand is unit elastic.
Ed < 1: Demand is inelastic.
Extreme Cases:
Ed = 0: Perfectly inelastic demand.
Ed = ∞: Perfectly elastic demand.
Perfectly Inelastic Demand:
Characterized by an vertical line on a graph indicating demand does not change with price.
Perfectly Elastic Demand:
Represented by a horizontal line indicating a small change in price leads to an infinite change in quantity demanded.
Total Revenue Formula: [ TR = Price \times Quantity ]
Total Revenue Test:
Inelastic demand: Price and Total Revenue move in the same direction.
Elastic demand: Price and Total Revenue move in opposite directions.
Example:
Lowering price leads to a gain (blue area) that exceeds loss (yellow area).
Example:
Lowering price leads to a loss (yellow area) that exceeds gain (blue area).
Example:
Lowering price results in equal gain (blue area) and loss (yellow area).
Summary Table:
Demand Categories:
Ed > 1: Elastic; Price increase decreases Total Revenue, Price decrease increases Total Revenue.
Ed = 1: Unit elastic; Total Revenue is unchanged with price changes.
Ed < 1: Inelastic; Price increase increases Total Revenue, Price decrease decreases Total Revenue.
Factors:
Substitutability: More substitutes mean more elastic demand.
Proportion of Income: Higher proportion means more elastic demand.
Luxury vs. Necessities: Luxury goods have more elastic demand.
Time: More time available increases elasticity of demand.
Examples:
Newspapers: 0.10, Milk: 0.63, Cigarettes: 0.25, Gasoline: 0.60, Restaurant meals: 2.27.
Implications:
Large crop yields can lead to lower revenue if demand is inelastic.
Excise taxes may yield more revenue when demand is inelastic.
Decriminalization of illegal drugs could similarly influence demand and revenue.
Definition: Measures sellers’ responsiveness to price changes; elastic supply indicates producers are responsive, while inelastic indicates less responsiveness.
Formula:
[ Es = \frac{\text{Percentage Change in Quantity Supplied}}{\text{Percentage Change in Price}} ]
Elastic Supply: [ Es > 1 ]
Unit Elastic Supply: [ Es = 1 ]
Inelastic Supply: [ Es < 1 ]
Perfectly Inelastic Supply: [ Es = 0 ]
Time Periods:
Immediate market period: Perfectly inelastic supply.
Short run: More elastic than immediate period.
Long run: Even more elastic than short run.
Examples:
Antiques: Inelastic supply.
Reproductions: More elastic supply.
Volatile gold prices: Inelastic supply.
Formula:
[ Exy = \frac{\text{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded of X}}{\text{Percentage Change in Price of Y}} ]
Responsiveness:
Positive elasticity indicates substitute goods.
Negative elasticity indicates complementary goods.
Zero elasticity indicates independent goods.
Formula:
[ Ei = \frac{\text{Percentage Change in Quantity Demanded}}{\text{Percentage Change in Income}} ]
Normal Goods: Positive elasticity.
Inferior Goods: Negative elasticity.
Definitions:
Positive cross elasticity indicates substitutes.
Negative cross elasticity indicates complements.
Positive income elasticity indicates normal goods.
Negative income elasticity indicates inferior goods.
Strategies:
Implementing different pricing strategy based on demand elasticity to maximize revenue.