Introduction to the concept of price elasticity in economics, focusing on its significance in understanding consumer behavior in response to price changes.
Overview of Chapter 4, emphasizing the importance of demand and supply elasticity in economic analysis in the context of the course material.
Demand curves are typically downward sloping.
Price increase leads to a decrease in quantity demanded.
Price elasticity quantifies this relationship between price and quantity demanded.
Example of demand elasticity using rugby ticket prices.
Table of prices, ticket demand (in thousands), and price elasticity of demand:
Price $12.50: 0 tickets demanded (Elasticity: -∞)
Price $10.00: 20 tickets (Elasticity: -4)
Price $7.50: 40 tickets (Elasticity: -1.5)
Price $5.00: 60 tickets (Elasticity: -0.67)
Price $2.50: 80 tickets (Elasticity: -0.25)
Price $0.00: 100 tickets (Elasticity: 0)
Measures how sensitive the quantity demanded is to changes in price.
Mathematical equation and explanation for calculating elasticity.
Example provided for calculating PED using rugby tickets and the effects of a price change:
10% price drop leads to an increase in demand by 8,000 tickets.
At $10, quantity demanded is 20,000 tickets; calculation of percentage change in quantity and elasticity.
Percentage change formula and its application in this context.
Introduction to alternative methods such as arc elasticity and point elasticity.
Focus on percentage change formula in this module.
Three classifications based on elasticity measures:
Elastic when |PED| > 1
Unit elastic when |PED| = 1
Inelastic when |PED| < 1
Key question: Which change is greater, price change or quantity demanded change?
Definition: Demand is elastic when % change in quantity demanded exceeds % change in price.
Example provided: A 7% drop in quantity in response to a 5% price increase yields an elasticity of -1.4.
Case study of Apple reducing iPhone prices resulting in tripled quantity sold.
EasyJet founder's approach to pricing strategy based on elasticity insights, achieving 85% sold seats compared to 75% of competitors.
Definition: Demand is inelastic when % change in quantity demanded is less than % change in price.
Example given: If a 5% price increase results in a 3.5% quantity drop, calculations provided.
Definition: Demand is unit elastic when % changes in quantity and price are equal, yielding |PED| = 1.
Example: 5% drop in quantity for a 5% price increase.
Discussion on how elasticity varies along a straight-line demand curve and implications for revenue.
Graphical representation of demand for rugby tickets at various prices and the associated quantities demanded.
Explanation of how elasticity differs for non-linear demand curves, including the impact of equal price changes on quantity demanded.
Key factors influencing price elasticity:
Availability of substitute goods leads to higher elasticity.
Example comparison between specific brands versus general categories (e.g., detergent).
Impact of elasticity on farmers:
A poor harvest can increase revenue if demand is inelastic.
Individual farmer crop demand is elastic due to substitutability (buying from neighbors).
Demand generally is more elastic in the long run compared to the short run, emphasizing consumer adaptability over time.
Illustrations of inelastic and elastic demand across different timeframes.
Objectives include:
Understanding and applying definitions of price elasticity of demand.
Differentiating between elastic, inelastic, and unit elastic scenarios.
Practicing elasticity calculations using percentage changes.
Exploring determinants that affect elasticity.