Regulation
Broadly: any system of norms, rules or restrictions that control, govern or direct behaviour.
Working definition (Deakin & Cook, 1999): “The control of corporate and commercial activities through a system of norms and rules which may be promulgated by government, private actors, or a combination of both.”
Key insight: state involvement is not essential; industry associations and professional bodies can create binding rules.
Dictionary anchors (OED)
Regulate = to control, govern, direct.
Regulation = the act/fact of regulating.
Accountability
Two indispensable elements (Nicholson et al., 2017):
An obligation to justify, explain, or take responsibility for actions against an expected standard.
The explanation must be open to debate, challenge, and consequences.
OED: “Liability to account for and answer for one’s conduct, duties, or performance.”
A simple heuristic: Accountability = Obligation + Justification + Consequences
They are two sides of one civilisational coin:
Regulation without accountability ⇒ toothless / potentially harmful (no enforcement).
Accountability without clear regulation ⇒ unfair (people judged on unknown standards).
Everyday arenas of accountability:
Legal – courts, statutory penalties.
Market – consumer response to products/services.
Managerial – HR processes, committees, performance reviews.
Visual mnemonic: “Regulation sets the standard; accountability supplies the answer sheet & marking rubric.”
Continuum of individual choice (high ➔ low)
Self-regulation – e.g. company codes of conduct, policies.
Voluntary adoption – e.g. ASX Corporate Governance Principles, industry codes.
Contractual adoption – e.g. supplier-imposed standards.
Societal (legal) regulation – e.g. \text{Corporations Act 2001 (Cth)}, negligence law, consumer norms.
Key takeaway: Law is only one form; expectations can be layered, dynamic, and organisation-specific.
Created under \text{Corporations Act 2001 (Cth)}; registration by ASIC gives birth to the company.
Two defining characteristics:
Separate legal entity (Salomon v Salomon): can own property, sue/be sued, contract, issue shares (s124).
Limited liability: shareholders’ loss capped at unpaid share capital; contrasts with unlimited liability of sole traders/partnerships.
Problem of personhood: a company is a legal fiction – it cannot be imprisoned; thus accountability must locate human decision-makers.
The Constitution (statutory contract under s140) binds members (shareholders), directors and management; can rely on Replaceable Rules (s134, s198A).
Directors hold residual decision power; often delegate to CEO & Officers.
Accountability mechanisms include:
Directors’ & Officers’ duties (Module 12).
Internal committees, board oversight, shareholder votes.
Three archetypes (think of overlapping circles, not silos):
Central authority ⇒ top-down control; formalised rules, sanctions, rewards.
Pros: clear expectations, consistency, traceable accountability.
Cons: rigidity, slow response, higher admin cost.
Examples: traditional reporting lines; legal fines; dismissal letters.
Governance via shared values, culture, peer pressure.
Pros: flexible, low formal cost, adaptable.
Cons: ambiguity, reliance on group cohesion, difficult to scale.
Examples: board culture, agile work teams, professional ethos (e.g. medical rounds).
Behaviour shaped by economic signals from affected parties.
Pros: efficiency, scalability, low direct cost.
Cons: information quality critical; risk of regulatory capture.
Examples: Uber’s star-rating system; open customer reviews; emissions-trading schemes.
Traditional taxi industry = hierarchical (licensing, quotas).
Uber introduced a market-based feedback loop (rider ratings) & clan elements (driver community norms) ➔ blurred the old hierarchy.
Real firms blend mechanisms:
Hierarchy: internal compliance office.
Clan: board/partner culture.
Market: shareholder activism, brand reputation.
Central policy question: “Should we regulate? If yes, how much & why?”
Two big umbrellas:
Public Interest Theories – regulation pursues collective welfare.
Private Interest Theories – regulation often serves narrower, self-interested groups.
Trigger: market failure – when unregulated markets misallocate resources.
Failure types & examples:
Monopoly/Oligopoly – energy, telecom; leads to \text{Competition Law}.
Network effects – telephones, social media (value ↑ with users). Regulation can maintain openness/interoperability.
Public goods – non-rival, non-excludable (street lighting, national defence). Private supply leads to free-rider problem; regulation (taxes) funds provision.
Conceptual formula: \text{Total Social Welfare} = \text{Consumer Surplus} + \text{Producer Surplus}; regulation seeks to maximise this sum under failure conditions.
Normative driver: fairness, redistribution, irreversible risk prevention.
Examples:
Income tax & social security (wealth transfer).
Anti-discrimination statutes, animal welfare.
Environmental laws tackling climate-change (inter-generational equity).
Assumption: actors maximise self-interest; regulation can be hijacked.
Phenomena:
Regulatory failure – costs > benefits (e.g. constant jaywalking fines impractical).
Regulatory capture (Posner): agency drifts toward the industry; voices of wealthy/noisy interest groups dominate.
Implication: scepticism toward “pure” public-interest claims; need checks & balances.
What is a regulator?
Government itself (ministers, departments).
Industry bodies.
Statutory authorities – semi-independent, created by Acts, funded & report to Government.
Core functions: investigate, enforce, gather complaints, educate.
ACCC (Competition & Consumer Act 2010)
Competition policy, consumer protection, educational campaigns, infringement notices, court action.
ASIC (ASIC Act + Corporations Act)
Oversees companies, financial markets, services, credit, superannuation.
ATO (Tax & Super systems)
Revenue collection, issues binding Tax Rulings (quasi-precedent), possesses wide audit powers.
Framework (Frooman 1999): Resource Control vs Decision Influence.
Withholding resources – consumer boycotts, supplier embargos, labour strikes.
Over-supply / targeted purchasing – buy-cotts supporting ethical firms (e.g. Fair-Trade coffee).
Direct power – shareholder resolutions, board seats, employee representation.
Indirect power – coalition-building, media campaigns, NGO partnerships.
Recognise multi-layered regulation: legal minima + soft-law + cultural norms.
Map which mechanism (hierarchical, clan, market) dominates each issue.
Guard against capture: diversify advisory inputs, rotate personnel, ensure transparency.
Balance efficiency (market signals) with equity (political goals) & stability (hierarchy).
Anticipate stakeholder strategies: design proactive engagement pathways.
Module 10 (Business Structures): limited vs unlimited liability context for accountability.
Module 12 (Director & Officer Duties): personal legal responsibilities anchoring the constitutional delegation of power.
Ethics module: interplay of normative claims (political public-interest) with utilitarian cost-benefit (welfare economics).
Concept | One-Line Definition | Key Example |
---|---|---|
Regulation | System of norms controlling behaviour | \text{Corporations Act 2001} |
Accountability | Obligation + Explanation + Consequences | CEO appears before Senate committee |
Hierarchy | Top-down rule enforcement | Disciplinary warnings |
Clan | Culture & peer norms | Board etiquette |
Market | Incentive via competition | Uber star ratings |
Welfare Econ | Fix market failure | Monopoly utility pricing cap |
Political | Justice & redistribution | Anti-discrimination Act |
Capture | Regulator serves industry | Revolving door lobbyists |
ACCC | Competition watchdog | Grocery-price collusion case |
ASIC | Corporate/financial regulator | Prospectus mis-statement fine |
ATO | Tax & super collector | GST audits |
“H-C-M ⇒ P.I. vs P.I. ⇒ A-A-A”
Hierarchy, Clan, Market mechanisms ⇢ balance.
Public-Interest vs Private-Interest theories ⇢ motive lens.
ACCC, ASIC, ATO ⇢ core regulators.
End of comprehensive study notes.