Consumer Choice — Key Concepts
Premises of Consumer Behaviour
Consumers have tastes/preferences that determine satisfaction from goods and services.
Consumers face constraints (income, prices, legal restrictions).
Consumers maximize well-being from consumption given constraints.
Five main topics
Preferences: predict bundles a consumer prefers
Utility: summarises preferences via utility functions
Budget constraint: prices, income limit purchases
Constrained consumer choice: maximize pleasure given income and prices
Behavioral economics: experiments show deviations from full rationality
Preferences and preference relations
Preferences are used to rank bundles; denote strict preference (e.g., a ≻ b), weak preference (a ≽ b), and indifference (a ~ b).
A consumer has a complete and transitive ranking of all bundles.
Assumptions about consumer preferences
Completeness: any two bundles can be ranked (a ≽ b, b ≽ a, or a ~ b).
Transitivity: if a ≽ b and b ≽ c, then a ≽ c.
More is Better: given the same other factors, more of a good is preferred to less (with exceptions for bads).
Indifference curves and maps
Indifference curve: set of bundles that yield the same level of utility.
Indifference map: complete set of indifference curves summarising a consumer’s tastes.
Properties of indifference maps
Bundles farther from the origin are preferred to those closer.
An indifference curve goes through every possible bundle.
Indifference curves cannot cross.
Indifference curves slope downward.
Indifference curves cannot be thick (no two bundles on a single curve should imply a strict preference for one over the other).
Impossibility of thick indifference curves
If a curve contained two bundles more of both goods than another, it would violate "more is better".
Willingness to substitute between goods (MRS)
MRS is the maximum amount of one good a consumer will sacrifice to obtain one more unit of the other good.
MRS is the slope of the indifference curve.
Formal: ext{MRS} = -\frac{\partial Z}{\partial B} = -\frac{MUZ}{MUB} where Z = pizzas and B = burritos.
Along an indifference curve, MRS can vary; often diminishing (convex to the origin).
Example: from bundle a to b, from b to c, etc., MRS can change (e.g., -3, -2, …).
Diminishing MRS: as you move down-right along an indifference curve, the MRS approaches zero; balanced baskets are preferred.
Utility and indifference curves
Utility: a numeric measure of satisfaction; indifference curves represent levels of utility.
Utility function: U(Z,B); e.g., U(Z,B) = Z^{0.5} B^{0.5}.
Marginal utility: the extra utility from consuming one more unit of a good; MUZ = \frac{\partial U}{\partial Z}, \quad MUB = \frac{\partial U}{\partial B}.
Marginal utility curves illustrate diminishing MU as consumption of the good rises.
Marginal rate of substitution and utility
At any point on an indifference curve, the MRS equals the slope of the curve: ext{MRS} = -\frac{MUZ}{MUB}.
Relationship to utility: the MRS is derived from the marginal utilities and shows how substitutions affect utility.
Budget constraint
Budget line: all bundles affordable with given income and prices; pB B + pZ Z = Y.
Opportunity set: all bundles on or inside the budget constraint.
Solving for burritos: B = \frac{Y - pZ Z}{pB} = \frac{Y}{pB} - \frac{pZ}{p_B} Z.
Example: if pZ=1, pB=2, Y=50, then B = 25 - \tfrac{1}{2}Z.
Slope of the budget constraint (MRT): \text{slope} = \frac{\Delta B}{\Delta Z} = -\frac{pZ}{pB}.
Shifts in the budget constraint
If price of pizza doubles (p_Z from 1 to 2), slope changes from -1/2 to -1 (steeper in B-Z space).
If income increases, the budget line shifts right (more affordable combinations).
Constrained consumer choice and optimum
The optimal bundle is the affordable bundle that yields the highest utility.
Interior solution: tangency condition where indifference curve is tangent to the budget line, i.e., ext{MRS} = \text{MRT} = \frac{pZ}{pB} or equivalently \frac{MUZ}{MUB} = \frac{pZ}{pB}.
Corner solution: occurs when tangency cannot be achieved within the budget; MRS may not equal MRT.
The cost-per-dollar rule for optimality
At optimum, utility per dollar spent should be equalized across goods:
\frac{MUZ}{pZ} = \frac{MUB}{pB} (assuming interior solution).
Special cases in preferences and indifference curves
Perfect substitutes: indifference curves are straight lines; consumers are indifferent between equal-rate substitutions; MRS is constant (e.g., slope -1 for 1-for-1 trade).
Perfect complements: indifference curves are L-shaped; goods are consumed in fixed proportions; no substitution.
Imperfect substitutes (standard goods): indifference curves are convex to the origin.
Practical examples and figures (conceptual summaries)
Joe’s two candy bars and one cake as perfect substitutes: MRS = -2 when moving between combos (slope -2 in the plotted space).
Indifference curves cannot be thick; attempting to form thick curves leads to violations of preference properties.
Utility function examples: 3D utility, e.g., U(X,Y) = X^{0.5} Y^{0.5}; MUX and MUY are the slopes of the utility surface.
Ordinal vs cardinal preferences
Ordinal: only ranking matters (relative order); does not quantify how much better.
Cardinal: absolute differences matter (e.g., money), but in consumer choice, ordinal utility is usually the focus.
Key takeaways (concise)
Preferences are complete, transitive, and “more is better” in standard cases.
Indifference curves are downward-sloping, convex (except in special cases), cannot cross or be thick.
MRS is the slope of the indifference curve and equals the negative ratio of marginal utilities: \text{MRS} = -\frac{MUZ}{MUB}.
Budget constraint shows all affordable bundles; slope equals the MRT: \text{MRT} = \frac{pZ}{pB}.
Interior optimum occurs where \text{MRS} = \text{MRT} or equivalently \frac{MUZ}{MUB} = \frac{pZ}{pB}; at optimum, \frac{MUZ}{pZ} = \frac{MUB}{pB}.
Special cases: perfect substitutes (straight-line ICs), perfect complements (L-shaped ICs), standard goods (convex ICs).
Practice questions (summary)
Q1: If preferences are complete and transitive, what does this imply? -> Consistent rankings of bundles.
Q2: The MRS between X and Y is: -\frac{MUY}{MUX} and equals the slope of the indifference curve; at optimum, equals the MRT (i.e., ratio of prices).
Q3: Not a property of indifference curves? They cannot cross; they slope downward; they cannot be thick; they farther from origin imply higher utility.
Q4: At consumer optimum (interior): \text{MRS} = \text{MRT} and all income is allocated to goods that give the most utility per dollar when possible.