Price elasticity of demand: Measures how much the quantity demanded of a product changes due to a change in its price.
Coefficient of elasticity: Denoted by epsilon (\varepsilon) . It's an absolute number, so the sign is ignored.
Formula: \varepsilon_p = \frac{\% \Delta \text{ quantity demanded}}{\% \Delta \text{ price}}
Inelastic Demand: Quantity demanded is not very responsive to price changes.
|\varepsilon| < 1
Elastic Demand: Quantity demanded is very responsive to price changes.
|\varepsilon| > 1
Unitary Demand: Percentage change in quantity demanded equals the percentage change in price.
|\varepsilon| = 1
Measures the responsiveness of quantity demanded to price changes.
If |\varepsilon| > 1, demand is elastic.
If |\varepsilon| < 1, demand is inelastic.
If |\varepsilon| = 1, demand is unitary.
Number of available substitutes.
Percentage of household income spent on the product.
Time period involved.
Elastic Demands
Fresh Tomatoes (4.60)
Movies (3.41)
Lamb (2.65)
Restaurant Meals (1.63)
China and Tableware (1.54)
Automobiles (1.14)
Inelastic Demands
Household Electricity (0.13)
Eggs (0.32)
Car Repairs (0.36)
Food (0.58)
Household Appliances (0.63)
Tobacco (0.86)
Sugar: Inelastic (\varepsilon < 1)
Gasoline: Inelastic (\varepsilon < 1)
Ocean Cruises: Elastic (\varepsilon > 1)
Restaurant Meals: Elastic (\varepsilon > 1)
Women's Hats: Elastic (\varepsilon > 1)
Alcohol: Inelastic (\varepsilon < 1)
Formula: \varepsilon_p = \frac{\% \Delta \text{ quantity demanded}}{\% \Delta \text{ price}}
Expanded Formula: \varepsilonp = \frac{\frac{\Delta Qd}{\text{average } Q_d} \times 100}{\frac{\Delta P}{\text{average } P} \times 100}
Vancouver to Edmonton
Price decreases from $650 to $550, quantity of tickets increases from 1000 to 1100.
\% \Delta Q_d = \frac{100}{1050} \times 100 = 9.5\%
\% \Delta P = \frac{-100}{600} \times 100 = -16.7\%
\varepsilon_p = \frac{9.5\%}{16.7\%} = 0.57
Demand is inelastic because \varepsilon_p < 1
Vancouver to Calgary
Price decreases from $650 to $550, quantity of tickets increases from 1000 to 1250.
\% \Delta Q_d = \frac{250}{1125} \times 100 = 22.2\%
\% \Delta P = \frac{-100}{600} \times 100 = -16.7\%
\varepsilon_p = \frac{22.2\%}{16.7\%} = 1.33
Demand is elastic because \varepsilon_p > 1
Set I: Price changes from $9 to $8, quantity changes from 1 to 2.
\varepsilon = \frac{(2-1)/1.5}{(9-8)/8.5} = \frac{66.66\%}{11.76\%} = 5.67
Set II: Price changes from $2 to $1, quantity changes from 8 to 9.
\varepsilon = \frac{(9-8)/8.5}{(2-1)/1.5} = \frac{11.76\%}{66.66\%} = 0.18
The coefficients are different because the same $1 change in price represents a small percentage change in Set I but a large percentage change in Set II. Similarly, the change of 1 unit in quantity represents a large percentage change in Set I, but a small percentage change in Set II.
If demand is elastic, an increase in price will decrease revenue.
If demand is inelastic, an increase in price will increase revenue.
If demand is inelastic (\varepsilon < 1):
Price falls, Total Revenue falls.
Price rises, Total Revenue rises.
If demand is elastic (\varepsilon > 1):
Price falls, Total Revenue rises.
Price rises, Total Revenue falls.
If demand is unitary elastic (\varepsilon = 1):
Price falls, Total Revenue stays the same.
Price rises, Total Revenue stays the same.
Revenue is not the same as profit.
\varepsilon > 1 and price falls: Total Revenue rises.
\varepsilon < 1 and price rises: Total Revenue rises.
\varepsilon < 1 and price falls: Total Revenue falls.
\varepsilon > 1 and price rises: Total Revenue falls.
\varepsilon = 1 and price rises: No change in Total Revenue.
Product A: \varepsilon = 2, price increases by 5%.
\% \Delta Q = -10\%, Total Revenue decreases.
Product B: \varepsilon = 0.4, price increases by 10%.
\% \Delta Q = -4\%, Total Revenue increases.
Product C: \varepsilon = 0.2, price decreases by 20%.
\% \Delta Q = 4\%, Total Revenue decreases.
Product D: \varepsilon = 1, price increases by 7%.
\% \Delta Q = -7\%, Total Revenue shows no change.
Product E: \varepsilon = 3, price decreases by 2%.
\% \Delta Q = 6\%, Total Revenue increases.
Slope is rise over run.
A straight-line demand curve has a constant slope.
Elasticity is percentage change in quantity over percentage change in price.
A straight-line demand curve's elasticity varies from point to point.
The upper half of any straight-line demand curve is elastic, and the lower half is inelastic.
A relatively steep demand curve is mostly inelastic.
A relatively shallow demand curve is mostly elastic.
Inelastic demand: A percentage change in price causes a smaller percentage change in quantity.
Unit elastic demand: A percentage change in price causes the same percentage change in quantity.
Elastic demand: A percentage change in price causes a larger percentage change in quantity.
As price drops from $10 to $5, demand is elastic, and total revenue increases.
At $5, demand is unitary, and total revenue is at its maximum.
Below $5, upon a drop in price, demand is inelastic, and total revenue is falling.
Perfectly inelastic: \varepsilon = 0
Inelastic: 0 < |\varepsilon| < 1
Unitary elastic: |\varepsilon| = 1
Elastic: |\varepsilon| > 1
Perfectly elastic: \varepsilon = \infty
With inelastic demand, the gain in total revenue from increased purchasing is less than the loss from a drop in price (but an increase in price will increase total revenue).
With unit elastic demand, the gain in total revenue from increased purchasing is equal to the loss from a drop in price.
With elastic demand, the gain in total revenue from increased purchasing is greater than the loss from a drop in price (but an increase in price will decrease total revenue).
Demand Schedule
Price Quantity
1 18
2 16
3 14
4 12
5 10
6 8
7 6
8 4
9 2
The slope of this demand curve is \frac{\Delta P}{\Delta Q} = \frac{1}{-2} = -0.5
The elasticity coefficient for a price change from, say, 4 to 5 is 0.82, which is quite different from the slope of –0.5. The elasticity varies along any curve where the slope is constant.
Sales tax.
Excise tax on products such as cigarettes.
Crackdown on illegal drugs.
A good harvest is not always good news for farmers.
The more inelastic the demand for a product, the larger is the percentage of a sales (or excise) tax the consumer will pay.
A sales tax imposed on a particular product.
They are an “easy” form of tax revenue for governments.
Taxes are usually imposed on products with inelastic demands (gasoline, cigarettes, alcohol) where the resulting increase in price is bigger than the drop in quantity.
The result: greater tax revenue for governments.
Salt (inelastic demand)
TAX REVENUES BEFORE TAX INCREASE: 10m.units @ $2 = $20m
TAX REVENUES AFTER $1 TAX INCREASE: 9m.units @ $3 = $27m
Tomatoes (elastic demand)
TAX REVENUES BEFORE TAX INCREASE: 10m.units @ $2 = $20m
TAX REVENUES AFTER $1 TAX INCREASE: 6m.units @ $3 = $18m
With an inelastic demand, a campaign against the drug trade will reduce the supply causing a great increase in the price, thus increasing the amount paid by drug users.
The demand for many agricultural products (including grain crops like rice and wheat) is inelastic.
An increase in the supply causes a big drop in the price so that the total revenue of farmers decreases.
A measure of how much quantity supplied changes as a result of a change in price.
\varepsilon_S = \frac{\% \Delta \text{ quantity supplied}}{\% \Delta \text{ price}}
Expanded Formula: \varepsilonS = \frac{\frac{\Delta QS}{\text{average } Q_S} \times 100}{\frac{\Delta P}{\text{average } P} \times 100}
Price changes from $2 to $3, the quantity supplied rises from 400 to 500.
\varepsilon_S = \frac{\frac{100}{450} \times 100}{\frac{1}{2.5} \times 100} = \frac{+0.22}{+0.4} = +0.55
In the market period, supply is perfectly inelastic.
In the short run, supply is inelastic.
In the long run, supply is elastic.
Longer time frames have more elastic supply.
Some products have perfectly inelastic supply.
E.g., concert tickets for a single event.
If demand is higher than the expected, there will be a shortage and ticket scalping.
If demand is lower than expected, there will be unsold seats.
The responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in income.
\varepsilonY = \frac{\% \Delta \text{ quantity demanded } (QD)}{\% \Delta \text{ income } (Y)}
Expanded Formula: \varepsilonY = \frac{\frac{\Delta QD}{\text{average } Q_D} \times 100}{\frac{\Delta Y}{\text{average } Y} \times 100}
If |\varepsilon_Y| > 1 (positive number): Normal – Luxury good, Income elastic.
If 0 < |\varepsilon_Y| < 1 (positive number): Normal – Necessity, Income inelastic.
If |\varepsilon_Y| < 0 (negative number): Inferior good, Negative income elastic.
Income, Quantity Demanded of X, Quantity Demanded of Y
$10,000, 200, 50
$15,000, 350, 54
Product X:
\varepsilon = \frac{(350-200)/275}{(15000-10000)/12500} = \frac{+54.5\%}{+40\%} = +1.36
Product Y:
\varepsilon = \frac{(54-50)/52}{(15000-10000)/12500} = \frac{+7.6\%}{+40\%} = +0.19
Products X and Y are normal goods because both have a positive coefficient.
X is a luxury (\varepsilon > 1).
Y is a necessity (0 < \varepsilon < 1).
Responsiveness of the change in Q_d of product A to a change in the price of product B.
\varepsilon_{AB} = \frac{\% \Delta \text{ quantity demanded of product A}}{\% \Delta \text{ price of product B}}
Expanded Formula: \varepsilon{AB} = \frac{\frac{\Delta Q{AD}}{\text{average } Q{AD}} \times 100}{\frac{\Delta PB}{\text{average } P_B} \times 100}
Margarine, Butter Price, Quantity Demanded per Week (lb.), Price, Quantity Demanded per Week (lb.)
$1.50, 5000, $3.00, 1000
$2.10, 3200, $3.00, 2000
\varepsilon_{AB} = \frac{\frac{1000}{1500} \times 100}{\frac{0.6}{1.8} \times 100} = +2
If coefficient is positive, goods are substitutes.
If coefficient is negative, goods are complements.
PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY
Inelastic: 0 to 1
Unitary: 1
Elastic: 1 to \infty
INCOME ELASTICITY
Inferior Goods: Negative Elasticity
Normal Goods
Necessities: Inelastic, 0 to 1
Luxuries: Elastic: 1 to \infty
CROSS-ELASTICITY
Complements: Negative Elasticity
Substitutes: Positive Elasticity
Definition, calculation, and determinants of price elasticity of demand.
Difference between slope and elasticity.
Relationship between elasticity and total revenue.
Real-world examples of elasticity.
Elasticity of supply, income elasticity, and cross-elasticity of demand.