Microeconomics 2 – Chapter 16 Study Notes: Externalities, Property Rights & Coase Theorem
Externalities & Market Efficiency
Guiding question: “How much of activity x should society undertake?”
Basic economic rule: Continue an activity until marginal cost (MC) equals marginal benefit (MB).
Individual illustration: Keep buying cake slices as long as the extra slice’s pleasure > its price.
Market illustration: In perfect competition, producers supply output where MC = P (price equals individual demand) ⇒ private markets yield Pareto-efficient allocations when no externalities are present.
Problem: If producing a cake (or any good) inflicts unpriced health damage on nearby residents, market prices no longer capture social cost ⇒ competitive outcome becomes inefficient.
Formal efficiency condition
Society should undertake activity x if SB(x) > SC(x), where SB and SC are social benefit and social cost functions.
With externalities: divergence appears ⇒ markets allocate too much (negative externality) or too little (positive externality) of the activity.
Defining Externalities
Broad idea: An externality exists when actions by one economic actor directly affect the utility or profit of another without compensation through market prices.
Not an externality: a demand shift that raises a good’s price (effect occurs through the price system).
Refined definition (captures decision calculus):
Activity carried out by Agent A imposes non-priced costs/benefits on others that A does not consider when choosing her optimal level.
Examples
Negative: Chemical plant pollutes river → downstream fishery’s catch falls.
Positive: Beekeeper adds hives → adjacent apple orchard yields rise.
Efficient solution minimizes total harm, not necessarily the harm to a single party.
If negotiation is costless, parties can bargain to efficient allocation regardless of initial liability assignment.
Numerical Illustrations (Examples 16.1–16.5)
16.1: Payoff(Confectioner noise)=40; Cost to Doctor=60 → Efficient: shut down factory.
Whether confectioner is liable or not, bargaining (or liability) leads to shutdown; transfers differ.
16.2: Gain to confectioner=60; Cost to doctor=40 → Efficient: continue operating; again, legal rule changes only transfers.
16.3: Noise gain=40; Noise cost=60; Soundproofing cost=20 → Efficient: install soundproofing and keep operating (Total NB=80). Occurs under either liability regime.
16.4: Same as 16.3 plus doctor can rearrange office for 18 (even cheaper) → Efficient: doctor rearranges (Total NB=82). Happens under both regimes; side payments ensure correct party bears cost ( 18≤P≤20 ).
16.5: Gain=60; Cost=40; Soundproof=20; Negotiation cost=25 → Efficient: install soundproofing, but only achieved if confectioner liable because costly bargaining prevents agreement when not liable. Demonstrates importance of transaction costs.
The Coase Theorem & Property Rights
Statement: If property rights are well-defined and transaction costs are zero, private bargaining leads to an efficient allocation of resources, independent of who initially holds the rights.
Logic: Rights create tradable entitlements (e.g., “right to make noise” vs. “right to silence”). Parties negotiate to the outcome maximizing joint surplus.
Real-world caveats:
Transaction costs (information, bargaining, enforcement) often non-negligible and rise with number of parties.
Defining complete, enforceable rights may be infeasible (e.g., air quality, biodiversity).
Hence governments use taxes, quotas, liability laws, standards.
Distributional note: Initial rights affect who pays/receives compensation, though not efficiency (with zero T-costs).
Application: Public-place Smoking Ban
Two assumptions underlying bans:
Negotiations with strangers in public are impractical ⇒ high T-costs.
Societal valuation of nonsmokers’ clean air > smokers’ utility from smoking.
Government Intervention I: Pigouvian Taxation
Principle: Levy tax t on externality-causing agent equal to marginal external damage \frac{\partial C2}{\partial x1}=a.
In 2-firm model, tax t=a induces Firm 1 to choose efficient x_1^{PE}.
Requirements & pitfalls:
Government must know marginal damage function (informational challenge).
Might mis-target the party with lowest avoidance cost ⇒ inefficient.
When bargaining is costless, Pigouvian tax may distort (over-correct) because private negotiations would have solved problem.
Example 16.9: Doctor can self-protect for 18 (cheapest), but tax on confectioner forces alternative, raising costs.
Government Intervention II: Tradable Emission Certificates
Mechanism: Authority sets total emissions cap Q and issues Q certificates; market determines price.
Firms with high abatement costs buy certificates; low-cost firms sell after reducing emissions.
In equilibrium: MC_{abatement} equalized across firms ⇒ cost-effective attainment of cap.
Advantages
Achieves target at minimum total cost without government knowing each firm’s abatement cost.
Creates explicit price signal; compatible with heterogeneous firms.
Disadvantages / prerequisites
Cap must be binding (below baseline emissions).
Does not itself decide “optimal” cap level; government still needs social-cost information.
Example with two firms & five technologies (A–E)
Unregulated choice: both use A (4 t/day).
Policy comparisons:
Uniform 50 % mandate: each firm moves to C ⇒ total abatement cost = 150.
Tax =10: too low, no abatement.
Tax =25: only Firm 1 switches to C; emissions cut by 2 t.
Certificate trading (4 certificates): Market allocates 3 to Firm 2, 1 to Firm 1 → same emission pattern as Policy 4 but at minimum private cost 110; monetary transfers depend on initial allocation.
Relation to Coase: Unlike pure bargaining, government pre-sets cap; certificates trade only among emitters, not with victims of pollution. Efficiency stems from quota, not free-market internalization.
Positional Externalities
Definition: Externalities arising from relative (rank-based) competition — one agent’s improvement reduces others’ relative standing.
Example puzzle: Hockey players seldom wear helmets voluntarily but support mandatory rule.
Each player gains agility from skating without helmet, fearing competitive disadvantage if others abstain.
General environments: Job hours race, conspicuous consumption, academic grading curves.
Institutional responses that curb positional races:
Work-week limits (labor law).
State pension systems (force savings, reduce savings competition).
Workplace safety standards.
Anti-doping regulations in sports.
Ethical & Practical Implications
Externalities justify government intervention beyond laissez-faire on welfare grounds.
Property-rights approaches stress rule-of-law foundations and distributional consequences.
Pigouvian instruments target marginal damages but demand information; certificate trading solves cost-minimization yet not optimal-level dilemma.
Positional externalities spotlight domains where absolute welfare conflicts with relative status; efficient regulation may need to coordinate restraint.