Chapter 8: Comparative Advantage and Gains from Trade
Gains from Trade
- Definition: Gains from trade = the benefits created when resources, goods, or services are reallocated to better uses.
- In essence, everyone is better off after voluntary exchange.
- Core intuition
- You possess some items/services; others possess different ones.
- They value your items more than you do, and you value their items more than they do.
- Swap → both parties end up with higher overall satisfaction (economic surplus).
- Subleasing example
- You hold a 12-month apartment lease at college but plan to be home for the summer.
- A student with a summer internship in Atlanta needs housing for exactly those months.
- You sublease via Facebook Marketplace.
- For the summer, they value the apartment more than you; you value cash more than the unused apartment.
- Trade (apartment ⇄ money) → mutual gain.
Absolute Advantage vs. Comparative Advantage
Absolute Advantage
- Ability to produce a good/service using fewer inputs.
- If two people use identical inputs, the one who produces more output has the absolute advantage.
- Hat illustration: If you can make 10 hats with fewer materials or less time than another person, you hold an absolute advantage in hat-making.
- Limitation: Tells who is best, not who should do the task.
- Researcher story
- Lead professor (PhD) writes papers and codes/cleans data better than the RA.
- Yet society gains more if the professor writes & ideates while the RA cleans data, because the professor’s opportunity cost of data cleaning is extremely high.
Comparative Advantage
- Ability to perform a task at a lower opportunity cost.
- Opportunity cost principle → always ask “or what?” (what must be given up?).
- Task allocation rule: Assign each job to the person who gives up the least valuable alternative (the lowest OC).
- Everyone possesses a comparative advantage in something, even if they lack absolute advantage anywhere.
- List productivities (time per task) for every individual.
- Convert to opportunity cost
\text{OC}{i,\;task\;1}=\frac{\text{Time}{i,\;task\;1}}{\text{Time}_{i,\;task\;2}}
- Interprets how many units of task 2 are foregone when performing task 1.
- Compare OCs → lower OC ⇒ comparative advantage.
- Reallocate tasks accordingly to maximize total output.
Accounting Example: Natalie & Ryan
- Raw productivity (minutes per task)
- Balance an account: Natalie 30, Ryan 40
- Process a customer payment: Natalie 10, Ryan 10
- Opportunity-cost table
- Balance an account
OC{Natalie}=\frac{30}{10}=3 \text{ payments}
OC{Ryan}=\frac{40}{10}=4 \text{ payments} - Process a payment
OC{Natalie}=\frac{10}{30}=\tfrac{1}{3} \text{ account}
OC{Ryan}=\frac{10}{40}=\tfrac{1}{4} \text{ account}
- Comparative-advantage conclusions
- Balancing accounts → Natalie (3 < 4)
- Processing payments → Ryan (1/4 < 1/3)
- Specialization impact (120-minute reallocation)
- Natalie: +120 min balance ⇒ +4 accounts; −120 min payments ⇒ −12 payments
- Ryan: −120 min balance ⇒ −3 accounts; +120 min payments ⇒ +12 payments
- Net result: +1 balanced account with the same labor hours
Specialization & Gains From Trade
- “Same inputs → more output” once tasks match comparative advantage.
- Practical illustrations
- Dentist office: Hygienist handles x-rays & cleanings, freeing dentist for surgeries/fillings.
- Toyota: Design in Japan (designers’ CA), production in Kentucky (manufacturing CA).
- Key principle: Reallocate work from high-OC producers to low-OC producers to minimize total resources spent.
Comparative Advantage & International Trade
- The identical logic applies regardless of borders.
- Produce what you’re relatively good at; buy the rest.
- Whether trading with a neighbor or another nation, the driver is opportunity-cost minimization.
- Vocabulary
- Goods bought from abroad → imports
- Goods sold abroad → exports
- Dan’s lawn allegory
- Young Dan mowed neighbors’ yards for cash.
- As a successful plumber, his opportunity cost of yardwork skyrocketed.
- He hires Karla (teenager) to mow.
- Dan earns more from plumbing than the cost of Karla’s service; Karla earns more than alternative jobs.
- Critics claim a “trade deficit” for “Country Dan,” but overlook the wider gains: larger plumbing income + maintained yard.
The Power of Prices
- Prices = signals, incentives, and information bundles.
- Signals
- To sellers: how much buyers value a good (buyers’ marginal benefit).
- To buyers: how costly it is for producers to expand supply (sellers’ marginal cost).
- Incentives
- High price encourages sellers to produce more (profit motive) & buyers to conserve/seek substitutes.
- Facilitates coordination among strangers; market quantity adjusts until plans align.
- Information aggregation
- Markets synthesize dispersed knowledge.
- Prediction markets: contract prices incorporate new information (e.g., injured quarterback lowers a team’s odds).
Key Takeaways & Study Tips
- Comparative Advantage
- Allocate each task to the lowest-OC producer, not necessarily the most productive one.
- Gains from Trade
- Reallocating according to CA allows the economy to achieve greater output with unchanged resources.
- Specialization
- Focus on the activity where your OC is lowest; purchase other goods/services.
- Prices
- Act as decentralized guides, motivating mutually beneficial specialization & trade.
- Exam tip
- Draw two-person, two-task tables; practice computing OCs and identifying CA.
- Remember: Everyone has CA somewhere, even if one party is universally slower.