This section covers producer and consumer surplus, their fluctuations, and the effects of government price controls.
Without rent control, rent can be $2,500/month, and 2,000,000 apartments are rented.
Government-imposed rent ceiling of $1,500 leads to:
Supply decreases to 1,900,000 apartments.
Demand increases to 2,100,000 apartments.
Resulting in a shortage of 200,000 apartments.
Producer surplus can be visualized as the area of a triangle showing the profit transfer from landlords to consumers under price controls.
Areas of deadweight loss (triangles labeled B and C) indicate economic surplus lost due to decreased rentals.
Black markets may emerge where selling violates price regulations.
Shift towards short-term rentals (e.g., Airbnb) allows some alleviation of deadweight loss, but buyers/sellers lose legal protections.
Price controls can benefit some but harm others; typically induce economic inefficiency.
Normative analysis questions whether price controls are good or bad—no absolute right/wrong answers; it relies on personal values and judgments.
Taxes fund government activities; focus is on per unit taxes.
Per Unit Taxes:
Example: US federal excise tax of $0.184/gallon for gasoline.
Effect on cigarette market:
Without tax price equilibrium: $6/pack, 4,000,000,000 packs sold.
With $1 tax, the supply curve shifts, adjusting the equilibrium down to 3,700,000,000 packs at a higher consumer price of $6.90.
Producers receive $5.90 after tax.
Government tax revenue comprises consumer and producer surplus losses converted to tax revenue and new deadweight loss.
Excess Burden: Refers to deadweight loss from a tax.
Efficient taxes have a smaller excess burden relative to generated revenue.
Example: Gasoline tax shift from $2.50 to $2.58 increases financial burden on consumers, while sellers lose $0.02.
Tax incidence defines who actually bears the burden of a tax, influenced by supply/demand curve slopes.
Steeper demand curve means consumers bear more burden; flatter means consumers shift less impact.
Consumer surplus is the difference between the highest price consumers are willing to pay and the actual price paid (illustrated as area A).
Producer surplus is the lowest price sellers would accept versus price received (illustrated as area B).
Economic surplus is measured by the sum of these surpluses.
Deadweight loss refers to the lost economic surplus due to non-competitive equilibrium, represented in diagrams as areas not covered under normal circumstances (e.g., areas C and E).
Marginal benefit greater than marginal cost signifies inefficiency, reinforcing the equilibrium efficiency rule.
A binding price ceiling leads to producer surplus transfer to consumers (area C).
Price floors can cause over-supplying, benefiting consumers by lowering prices below equilibrium.
Black markets emerge when government controls prices, impacting surfaces negatively, with examples including rent controls.
Normative statements regarding rent controls reflect personal values on market regulation and its outcomes.
Economists generally caution against excessive government interference due to its potential to diminish living standards.
The imposition of price controls will always have winners and losers, leading to diminished economic efficiency overall.