LW

Labour Markets – Chapter 14 Detailed Notes

Motivating Examples: Scarcity of Unique Skills

  • Contrasting labour markets illustrate how scarcity and number of potential employers shape wages.
    • Romelu Lukaku (professional striker)
    • Annual salary ≈ € 7,500,000.
    • Many football clubs compete → high bargaining power for worker.
    • Ursula von der Leyen (President, EU-Commission)
    • Annual salary ≈ € 330,000.
    • Effectively single employer (EU) → monopsonistic element keeps wage relatively low.
  • Highlights
    • Competition on the demand side raises the price of scarce labour.
    • Monopsony / limited buyers depress wages even for highly skilled labour.

Chapter Road-Map

  • Short-run labour demand of a perfectly competitive firm.
  • Long-run labour demand of a perfectly competitive firm.
  • Aggregation to market demand for labour.
  • Adjustments under imperfect competition (monopoly/monopolistic competition).
  • Individual labour-supply decisions.
  • Applications: taxes, transfers, minimum wages, sectoral shifts.

1. Perfectly Competitive Firm – Short-Run Demand for Labour

  • Assumptions
    • Product market: perfect competition ⇒ price-taker; output price p fixed.
    • Capital K and technology fixed in SR; labour L variable.
    • Input markets perfectly competitive ⇒ constant wage w and rental rate r.
  • Technology & profit
    • Production function Q=f(L,K) (with \partial Q/\partial L>0, \partial^2 Q/\partial L^2<0).
    • Profit: \Pi=pQ-wL-rK.
    • First-order condition (FOC):
      \frac{\partial\Pi}{\partial L}=p\frac{\partial Q}{\partial L}-w=0 \Rightarrow p\,\text{MP}_L=w.
  • Key concepts
    • Marginal Product of Labour: \text{MP}_L=\partial Q/\partial L.
    • Value of Marginal Product: \text{VMP}L=p\,\text{MP}L.
    • Profit maximisation rule: \text{VMP}_L=w (i.e. MR=MC for labour).
  • Graphical illustration (Fig. 14.1)
    • Panel (a): \text{MP}_L curve slopes downward (diminishing marginal returns).
    • Panel (b): \text{VMP}_L downward; intersects horizontal wage line at optimal L.
    • Wage fall shifts equilibrium rightward (higher employment).
  • Numerical example (price p=10, w=10, fixed K=10{,}000, r=1)
    • Technology: Q=K\cdot L=10{,}000 L.
    • \text{MP}_L=10{,}000 (constant).
    • \text{VMP}_L=10\times10{,}000=100{,}000> w ⇒ corner solution: hire until capacity or other constraint; illustrates limitations of simplistic linear technology.

2. Perfectly Competitive Firm – Long-Run Demand for Labour

  • All inputs variable; firm chooses L and K to maximise profit subject to cost.
  • Cost (isocost) line: C=wL+rK; slope = -w/r.
  • Isoquant: combinations producing given q_0.
  • At optimum (point P) :
    \frac{\partial Q/\partial L}{\partial Q/\partial K}=\frac{w}{r} (tangency ⇒ MRTS equals input-price ratio).
  • Wage change decomposes:
    1. Substitution effect (movement along isoquant).
    2. Scale effect (parallel outward shift of isoquant if total cost changes).

Special Cases

  1. Perfect Complements (fixed proportions)
    • Short-run: wage fall no substitution (capital fixed), employment unchanged.
    • Long-run: both inputs and output expand; LR labour demand increases.
  2. Perfect Substitutes
    • Initial situation: if w>r \times (\text{MP}K/\text{MP}L) firm uses only capital.
    • Wage falls sufficiently ⇒ abrupt switch to labour-intensive technique; LR labour demand extremely elastic.
  • General elasticities
    • LR demand more elastic than SR because substitution possible only in LR.
    • Demand more elastic the more elastic product-demand and the easier input substitutability.

3. Market Demand for Labour under Perfect Competition

  • Horizontal sum of firms’ \text{VMP}_L curves at given output price.
  • Wage reduction sequence (Fig. 14.4):
    • Each firm moves down its \text{VMP}_L → higher L.
    • Aggregate output rises ⇒ market price p falls ⇒ each \text{VMP}_L curve shifts down.
    • Combined effect → market demand curve D is steeper than simple horizontal aggregation.
  • Implicit simplifying assumptions
    • Homogeneous labour & industry; perfect competition.
    • Reality: multiple types of labour employed across diverse sectors; when wage share in total cost small, simplified aggregation still reasonable (e.g. electricians example, 0.01 % of total labour cost).

4. Market Demand for Labour under Imperfect Competition

  • With market power, marginal revenue \text{MR}<p ⇒ define Marginal Revenue Product:
    \text{MRP}L = \text{MR}\times \text{MP}L.
  • Hiring rule: \text{MRP}_L = w.
  • Since \text{MRP}L
  • Diminishing returns still apply ⇒ SR curve downward sloping; LR more elastic.
  • Monopolist’s labour demand coincides with industry demand so no additional price-feedback adjustment when aggregating.

5. The Individual Supply of Labour

Preferences & Utility

  • Goods: Consumption income C vs Leisure hours h (with total time T, labour hours H=T-h).
  • Utility function U(C,h) with \partial U/\partial C>0, \partial^2U/\partial C^2<0; likewise for h.
    • Example: Cobb–Douglas U=C^{\alpha}h^{\beta},\ 0<\alpha,\beta<1.
  • Indifference curves downward-sloping; slope = Marginal Rate of Substitution:
    \text{MRS}_{h,C}=\frac{\partial U/\partial h}{\partial U/\partial C}= -\frac{\Delta C}{\Delta h}.

Budget Constraint

  • Monetary income: C = wH + V = w(T-h)+V = wT + V - wh.
  • Optimal choice solves
    \max_{h} U(C,h) \quad \text{s.t.} \; C=w(T-h)+V.
  • FOC ⇒ \text{MRS}_{h,C}=w: marginal value of leisure equals wage (opportunity cost of leisure).

Graphical Example (Fig. 14.5)

  • Parameters: w_0=10€, T=24, V=0.
  • Extreme bundles:
    • Full leisure h=24 ⇒ C=0.
    • Zero leisure h=0 ⇒ C=240€.
  • Optimum A: h^=15 ⇒ labour H^=9; income C^*=90€; indifference curve tangent to budget.

Comparative Statics

  • Wage rise rotates budget around C=V intercept.
  • Substitution effect: higher w → leisure more expensive → h falls.
  • Income effect: higher w raises real income → if leisure normal, h increases.
  • Combined result can create backward-bending supply: labour supplied increases at low wages, decreases at high wages (Fig. 14.7).
  • Perfect complements case (10 € income ↔ 1 h leisure)
    • Only income effect; at w=20€ optimum occurs where C=10h intersects budget: h=16, H=8.
  • Perfect substitutes case, same trade-off 10 € per 1 h leisure
    • Linear indifference curves: if w>10€ choose zero leisure (h=0), supply all time to work; if w<10€ supply none.

Target-Income Behaviour

  • Some workers aim for daily income target (e.g., taxi drivers).
    • Supply curve vertical at income objective: w\uparrow ⇒ hours H fall (Camerer et al., 1997).

6. Aggregate Labour Supply

  • Market supply is horizontal summation of individual supply curves (Fig. 2-12).
    • Entry margin: as wages rise, new workers enter labour force or switch sectors.
  • Even if some individuals reduce hours at high wages, aggregate curve typically upward sloping because:
    • Participation rises.
    • Cross-sector mobility (e.g., AI-engineer wages > 350{,}000 attract students into CS).

7. Policy Applications

7.1 Taxes & Transfers (David & Sarah examples)

  • Piece-wise linear budget constraints create kinks and low effective net wages.
  • David (low-skill)
    • Unemployment benefit €110, wage w=5€.
    • 0–€150 earnings zone: benefit withdrawn gradually ⇒ effective net wage €1.33/h.
    • Above €150: benefit lost; after 30 h, additional earnings taxed 20 % ⇒ net wage €4/h.
    • Optimal choice on given indifference curve: 0 hours (corner solution) ⇒ work disincentive.
  • Sarah (high-skill, w=30€)
    • First €150 untaxed; €150–€600 taxed 20 % ⇒ net 24€/h; above €600 taxed 60 % ⇒ net 12€/h.
    • Optimal hours ≈ 20 h where marginal utility of income equals flatter post-tax wage.
  • Trade-off for policy makers: provide safety net vs maintain work incentives.

7.2 Minimum Wage Legislation

  • Theory (competitive market)
    • If w{min}>\text{VMP}L ⇒ employment falls, unemployment emerges (Fig. 79: D–S diagram).
    • Adjustments: offshoring, capital-labour substitution, reduction of non-wage benefits.
  • Empirical evidence (meta-analysis of ~1,400 studies)
    • Mixed results; overall small negative employment effects, larger for youth, students, low-skill minorities.
    • Methodological issues: non-random policy, short-run vs long-run, other margins (quality, hours, benefits).
  • Recent research
    • Putty-clay model: entry/exit dynamics in restaurant industry (Aaronson et al., 2018).
    • Job growth more affected than immediate employment (Meer & West, 2016).
    • Automation risk: jobs with automatable tasks more likely to decline after hikes (Lordan & Neumark, 2018).

8. Key Equations & Definitions (Quick Reference)

  • Marginal Product of Labour: \text{MP}_L=\partial Q/\partial L.
  • Value Marginal Product: \text{VMP}L=p \times \text{MP}L.
  • Marginal Revenue Product (imperfect comp.): \text{MRP}L=\text{MR} \times \text{MP}L.
  • Hiring rule (competitive): \text{VMP}_L=w.
  • Hiring rule (imperfect): \text{MRP}_L=w.
  • Isocost: C=wL+rK; slope = -w/r.
  • Budget constraint individual: C=w(T-h)+V.
  • Labour supply elasticity (qualitative):
    • SR demand < LR demand (elasticity);
    • Market demand steeper than aggregate \text{VMP}_L due to price feedback.

9. Ethical & Practical Considerations

  • Minimum wage as living-wage policy vs potential unemployment.
  • Tax/transfer design must balance equity (safety net) with efficiency (incentives).
  • Monopsony power or imperfect competition justify deviations from competitive wage outcomes (e.g., living wage, minimum wage can raise both wage and employment in classical monopsony).
  • Sectoral shifts (e.g., AI boom) illustrate dynamic nature of labour allocation and importance of education policy.

10. Suggested Reading

  • Frank, R. H. & Cartwright, E. (2013). "Microeconomics and Behavior", Chapter 14.
  • Empirical studies: Camerer et al. 1997 (taxi drivers), Sorkin 2015, Aaronson et al. 2018, Meer & West 2016, Lordan & Neumark 2018.