Economics Lecture 4: Labour, Inequality, and Gender
Patterns and Trends
Topics to be discussed:
Patterns and trends in labor, inequality, and gender.
'Mainstream' approaches to labor, inequality, and gender.
Alternative approaches focusing on the specificity of labor.
Importance of gender considerations.
Why Inequality?
References to articles and reports discussing economic inequality:
Larry Elliott, 21 Jan 2019.
Richard Partington, 9 Sep 2019.
Financial Times, 5 November 2019.
The Economist, 28 November 2019.
Felicity Lawrence, The Guardian, 11 Apr 2020.
Counterfire, 7 April 2020.
The National Union of Public and General Employees (NUPGE), 7 April 2020.
Max Fisher and Emma Bubola, New York Times, March 15, 2020.
Global Income Inequality: T0.1/B50 Ratio, 1820-2020
Comparison of average income of the global top 0.1% to the bottom 50%.
1820: The top 0.1% earned 320 times more than the bottom 50%.
1910: The top 0.1% earned 875 times more than the bottom 50%.
2007: The top 0.1% earned 718 times more than the bottom 50%.
2020: The top 0.1% earned 602 times more than the bottom 50%.
The graph illustrates the trend of this ratio from 1820 to 2020.
Top 10% Income Shares Across the World, 2021
Income share of the top 10% varies across different regions:
Ranges from 26-40% in some regions.
Ranges from 40-43% in some regions.
Ranges from 43-46% in some regions.
Ranges from 46-49% in some regions.
Ranges from 49-83% in some regions.
Bottom 50% Income Shares Across the World, 2021
Income share of the bottom 50% varies across different regions:
Ranges from 3-12% in some regions.
Ranges from 12-14% in some regions.
Ranges from 14-16% in some regions.
Ranges from 16-17% in some regions.
Ranges from 17-25% in some regions.
Geographic Breakdown of Global Income Groups in 2021
Distribution of global income groups across different regions.
Regions include North America & Oceania, Europe, Russia & Central Asia, MENA, Latin America, Sub-Saharan Africa, China, Other Asia, and India.
Shares of total population within each income group are compared.
From 1% poorest to 0.001% richest.
Global Income Inequality: Between-Country vs Within-Country Inequality (Theil Index), 1820-2020
Decomposition of global inequality into between-country and within-country components using the Theil Index.
1820: Between-country inequality accounted for 11% of global inequality.
1980: Between-country inequality accounted for 57% of global inequality.
2020: Between-country inequality accounted for 32% of global inequality.
The graph shows the changing distribution of inequality between countries and within countries from 1820 to 2020.
Global Carbon Inequality, 2019: Emissions by Group
Carbon emissions per person per year for different income groups.
Full population: 6.6 tonnes of CO2e.
Bottom 50%: 1.6 tonnes of CO2e.
Middle 40%: 3.1 tonnes of CO2e.
Top 10%: 31 tonnes of CO2e.
Top 1%: 110 tonnes of CO2e.
The Elephant Curve of Global Inequality, 1980-2020
The Elephant Curve illustrates the cumulated growth of per capita real income between 1980 and 2020 across the global income distribution.
The bottom 50% captured 9% of total growth.
The top 1% captured 23% of total growth.
Highlights the rise of emerging countries and the lagging of lower and middle classes of rich countries.
Activity (1)
Factors explaining the 'elephant curve' of global inequality and growth.
Link to a Microsoft Forms survey: https://forms.office.com/e/FwCJpbCMSd
The 'Mainstream' Economic Approach to the Labour Market (1)
Income inequality is multidimensional, and schools of thought in labor economics offer different perspectives.
'Mainstream'/'orthodox' neoclassical economics views labor as a commodity, treating the labor market as any other market governed by supply and demand.
Wages depend on labor demand and supply, reflecting factor earnings with productivity under perfectly competitive markets.
The 'Mainstream' Economic Approach to the Labour Market (2)
Human capital theory (Becker 1964; Mincer 1974) suggests that inequality stems from skill formation (education, training, etc.).
Inequality from low wages or unemployment/underemployment can be attributed to institutions, policies, personal choices, or individual failings.
'Mainstream'/'orthodox' economists are generally less concerned with inequality.
Lucas (2004): economic analysis should prioritize increasing production over focusing on inequality or distribution.
Kuznets (1955) - Inverted-U Shaped Trend
The Kuznets curve illustrates that as income per capita rises, inequality initially increases but eventually decreases.
Activity (2)
What makes labor inherently different from other marketable commodities, such as broccoli, fresh fruit, or bags of concrete?
Link to a Microsoft Forms survey: https://forms.office.com/e/vJkyCwVWzF
Reference to Charles Chaplin in Modern Times (1936).
Specificity of Labour
Labor (power) cannot be separated from the laborer.
Labor (power) cannot be stored.
Labor is an active, self-conscious factor of production.
Alternatives: Institutional Approaches
Focus on labor market institutions (labor laws; unionization; collective bargaining) and the weakening of the welfare state.
Segmented labor market theories: historical emergence and reproduction of labor market structures.
Governance of firms: global inequality resulting from global value chains and concentration of surplus value in the global North.
Emphasis on institutional and policy interventions to tackle inequality, contrasting with 'mainstream' approaches.
Female Labor Income Share Across the World, 1990-2020
Trends in female labor income share across different regions:
Asia (excluding China).
China.
Russia & Central Asia.
Latin America.
MENA.
North America.
Sub-Saharan Africa.
Western Europe.
Comparison of income shares across years: 1990, 1995, 2000, 2005, 2010, 2015-2020.
Activity (3)
Why does gender inequality persist?
What is distinct about gender in capitalist society?
Link to a Microsoft Forms survey: https://forms.office.com/e/xRyuwcTi4G
Gender Pay Gap in the UK, 1997-2014 (Hourly Earnings £ Per Hour – Full-Time Workers)
The gender pay gap amongst those in full-time employment has been declining.
Little change in the gap in higher paid jobs.
The gap has narrowed because of the decline in male earnings at the bottom.
Source: ONS, Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings (ASHE) (2015) data modified from Figure 11.
Gender Differences in Part-Time and Flexible Work in the UK, 2014
Women make up only 36.7 per cent of full-time workers in the UK.
For part-time workers, the gender pay gap is significantly higher when compared to full-time men.
At the current rate of change, it will take 30 to 50 years to eliminate the gender wage gap for full-time workers and 300 years for female part-timers.
Pay Gap Between Mothers and Fathers (A) and Between Singles Without Children, UK 2014
Gender pay gap for parents widens from the age of 30, illustrating the so-called ‘motherhood pay penalty’.
For single men and women without children, the gap widens from the age of 40.
Source: Manning (2015) using LFS data.
Gender Difference in Time Spent in Paid and Unpaid Work, UK in 2008
Women in the UK on average spend a similar amount of time in total (both unpaid and paid) work to men.
However, women in the UK spend on average two hours more than men on unpaid work, generally caring for children and carrying out other household work.
Source: Razzu (2014: 15); OECD Secretariat estimates based on national time-use surveys.
From Labour Market to Labour Regime?
Alternative approaches highlight the specificity of labour (power).
Wages are not just costs but also sources of aggregate demand, productivity, and the basis to reproduce labour-power.
Over-emphasis on the labour ‘market’ underestimates the importance of unpaid work in sustaining the ‘regime’ of labour in capitalist society.