LW

Public Goods & Commons – Exam Study Notes

Perfect Competition & Preconditions

  • Recall from Microeconomics I:

    • Under the assumptions of perfect competition, market equilibria are Pareto-efficient.

    • Key prerequisite: all goods are private goods (both rivalrous and excludable).

  • If the good is not rivalrous and/or excludable, the standard invisible-hand result can fail, leading to inefficiencies.

Public Goods: Core Definitions & Intuition

  • Non-rivalry (non-diminishability)

    • Consumption by one individual does not reduce utility available to others.

    • Example: national defence – my protection does not diminish yours.

  • Non-excludability

    • Either impossible or prohibitively costly to exclude someone from consumption.

    • Example: once the country is protected, you cannot cheaply keep one citizen unprotected.

  • A good satisfying both traits fully is a pure public good.

    • Important distinction from a publicly provided good (simply financed/produced by government; may still be private in nature).

  • Provision can come from private sector or government; problem lies in incentives, not producer identity.

Taxonomy of Goods (Rivalry × Excludability Matrix)

Excludable

Non-excludable

Rivalrous

Pure private good (e.g. cup of coffee)

Common-pool resource / collective good (e.g. ocean fish stock)

Non-rivalrous

Club good (e.g. Netflix subscription, toll bridge at low traffic)

Pure public good (e.g. lighthouse/dike, broadcast signal)

  • Classification practice questions:

    • Clock tower → non-rival, non-excludable ⇒ pure public good.

    • Streets → depends on congestion; empty street acts like a club good, congested street becomes rivalrous.

    • Fundamental non-patentable research → pure public good.

    • Concert → excludable (ticketing) & rivalrous (seat scarcity) ⇒ private/club mix.

Inefficiency of Private Provision: Two-Person Diagram

  • Individuals A and B each have downward-sloping inverse demand (WTP) curves for a public good.

  • For public goods, social demand is the vertical sum (add WTPs at each quantity).

    • Efficient output where \sum WTP = MC (Samuelson condition).

  • Market outcome with private sellers:

    • Each behaves as if good is private ⇒ horizontal sum of demands; generally yields too low quantity.

    • If WTP_A < MC for all quantities, A buys none and free-rides on B.

  • Result: Q{private} < Q^{*}{Pareto}.

Samuelson Condition (Formal)

  • Efficiency requires
    \sum{i=1}^{n} MBi(Q) = MC(Q)
    where MBi equals marginal willingness to pay or marginal rate of substitution MRS{i}^{(G,X)} between public good G and private composite good X.

  • Equivalently, \sum{i} MRS{i}^{(G,X)} = MRT_{(G,X)}.

  • If condition not met, reallocating spending between private & public goods raises aggregate utility.

Free-Riding Dynamics

  • When benefits are non-excludable, individuals misreport or withhold contributions.

  • Scenarios:

    1. Both A and B have WTP < MC ⇒ zero voluntary supply despite positive social value.

    2. Both have WTP > MC but act independently ⇒ each hopes other will pay, total still < efficient.

  • Link to externalities: under-provision of public good is symmetric to positive externality (each unit confers uncompensated benefits on others).

Tragedy of the Commons (Common-Pool Resources)

  • Thought experiment: 6 villagers, each with 100 €; choice:

    1. Buy government bond (12 % return).

    2. Buy a steer grazing on shared commons.

  • Grazing density lowers individual steer weight → lower sale price (Table 16.7):
    1 steer → 120 €; … ; 6 steers → 105 €.

  • Individual decisions ignore negative externality on existing cattle; outcome: over-grazing (over-use).

  • Remedies:

    • Assign property rights (auction pastureland; Coasean bargaining).

    • Practical difficulties at large scale: whales in international waters, global warming, orbital satellites.

Government Intervention: Challenges & Tools

  • Non-rivalry/excludability imply private provision is costly & information-constrained.

  • Government needs individuals’ true WTP to set efficient quantity, but faces incentive-compatibility problem (people understate).

  • Broad categories of intervention:

    • Direct public provision & taxation.

    • Lindahl pricing (personalized prices; requires preference revelation).

    • Voting on discrete provision levels.

    • Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG)/Clarke tax mechanism.

    • Provision-point (Bagnoli–Lipman) mechanisms.

VCG / Clarke Tax Mechanism (Summary)

  • Steps:

    1. Individuals state maximum WTP for each alternative.

    2. Alternative with highest aggregate stated value is chosen.

    3. Each individual pays a tax only if her report is pivotal (decisive); tax equals net external effect on others.

  • Key properties:

    • Payment never exceeds own stated value.

    • No incentive to misrepresent preferences (dominant-strategy truth-telling).

  • Numerical Illustration (3 voters A, B, C; alternatives X vs Y):

    • Truthful values (in €): A: (1,3),\ B:(3,2),\ C:(3.5,2) ⇒ \sum{X}=7.5, \sum{Y}=7 ⇒ X wins.

    • A is not pivotal ⇒ tax 0.

    • Remove B ⇒ sums 4.5 vs 5 → Y would win; hence B pivotal, pays tax 5-4.5 = 0.5.

    • Remove C ⇒ sums 4 vs 5 → Y wins; C pivotal, pays tax 5-4 = 1.

    • Misreporting (A pretending Y = 4) flips choice; now A pivotal & pays tax 2.5 > personal gain ⇒ lying unprofitable.

Provision-Point (Crowdfunding-Style) Mechanism

  • Specify cost/target for public good.

  • Collect voluntary pledges C_i.

  • If \sum C_i \ge \text{target} → good provided; if not → money-back guarantee.

  • Eliminates risk of being sole contributor; minimal strategic complexity.

  • Real-world use: Kickstarter campaigns, minimum-signatory climate treaties, charity drives.

Behavioural Economics Evidence: Public Good Games

  • Standard lab design (3 players):

    • Each endowed with 5 €; chooses contribution C_i \in [0,5] to a common pool.

    • Pool is doubled and evenly split.

    • Monetary payoff: Yi = 5 - \frac{1}{3}Ci + \frac{2}{3}(Cj+Ck).

    • Self-interest prediction: Ci = 0; Pareto-efficient: Ci=5 for all.

  • Classroom data (single shot): average contribution 3.57 € (≈ 71 % endowment); 43 % fully cooperative.

  • Robust experimental regularities:

    • One-shot mean ≈ 50 % of endowment.

    • Contributions decay across rounds in repeated games (learning to free-ride).

    • Stable groups (fixed partners) sustain higher cooperation.

    • Introducing costly punishment opportunities markedly raises contributions.

    • Large share of participants are conditional cooperators – contribute proportionally to others’ average.

    • Conditional cooperation documented as early as age 6.

Implications & Open Problems

  • Although theory predicts zero voluntary provision, human behaviour features altruism, norms, reciprocity & punishment.

  • Free-riding remains substantial; private mechanisms rarely reach full efficiency.

  • Central policy challenge: preference aggregation – obtaining reliable WTP data to meet Samuelson condition.

  • Clarke tax & related mechanisms are elegant but prone to:

    • High informational demands, complexity, administrative cost, potential collusion.

  • No universal solution; mix of regulation, property rights, taxation, and institution design needed.

Numerical & Formal References

  • Steer price schedule: P(N) = 120 - 2(N-1) for N=1,\ldots,6 (implied by table).

  • Government bond return: r = 0.12 per annum.