Recall from Microeconomics I:
Under the assumptions of perfect competition, market equilibria are Pareto-efficient.
Key prerequisite: all goods are private goods (both rivalrous and excludable).
If the good is not rivalrous and/or excludable, the standard invisible-hand result can fail, leading to inefficiencies.
Non-rivalry (non-diminishability)
Consumption by one individual does not reduce utility available to others.
Example: national defence – my protection does not diminish yours.
Non-excludability
Either impossible or prohibitively costly to exclude someone from consumption.
Example: once the country is protected, you cannot cheaply keep one citizen unprotected.
A good satisfying both traits fully is a pure public good.
Important distinction from a publicly provided good (simply financed/produced by government; may still be private in nature).
Provision can come from private sector or government; problem lies in incentives, not producer identity.
Excludable | Non-excludable | |
---|---|---|
Rivalrous | Pure private good (e.g. cup of coffee) | Common-pool resource / collective good (e.g. ocean fish stock) |
Non-rivalrous | Club good (e.g. Netflix subscription, toll bridge at low traffic) | Pure public good (e.g. lighthouse/dike, broadcast signal) |
Classification practice questions:
Clock tower → non-rival, non-excludable ⇒ pure public good.
Streets → depends on congestion; empty street acts like a club good, congested street becomes rivalrous.
Fundamental non-patentable research → pure public good.
Concert → excludable (ticketing) & rivalrous (seat scarcity) ⇒ private/club mix.
Individuals A and B each have downward-sloping inverse demand (WTP) curves for a public good.
For public goods, social demand is the vertical sum (add WTPs at each quantity).
Efficient output where \sum WTP = MC (Samuelson condition).
Market outcome with private sellers:
Each behaves as if good is private ⇒ horizontal sum of demands; generally yields too low quantity.
If WTP_A < MC for all quantities, A buys none and free-rides on B.
Result: Q{private} < Q^{*}{Pareto}.
Efficiency requires
\sum{i=1}^{n} MBi(Q) = MC(Q)
where MBi equals marginal willingness to pay or marginal rate of substitution MRS{i}^{(G,X)} between public good G and private composite good X.
Equivalently, \sum{i} MRS{i}^{(G,X)} = MRT_{(G,X)}.
If condition not met, reallocating spending between private & public goods raises aggregate utility.
When benefits are non-excludable, individuals misreport or withhold contributions.
Scenarios:
Both A and B have WTP < MC ⇒ zero voluntary supply despite positive social value.
Both have WTP > MC but act independently ⇒ each hopes other will pay, total still < efficient.
Link to externalities: under-provision of public good is symmetric to positive externality (each unit confers uncompensated benefits on others).
Thought experiment: 6 villagers, each with 100 €; choice:
Buy government bond (12 % return).
Buy a steer grazing on shared commons.
Grazing density lowers individual steer weight → lower sale price (Table 16.7):
1 steer → 120 €; … ; 6 steers → 105 €.
Individual decisions ignore negative externality on existing cattle; outcome: over-grazing (over-use).
Remedies:
Assign property rights (auction pastureland; Coasean bargaining).
Practical difficulties at large scale: whales in international waters, global warming, orbital satellites.
Non-rivalry/excludability imply private provision is costly & information-constrained.
Government needs individuals’ true WTP to set efficient quantity, but faces incentive-compatibility problem (people understate).
Broad categories of intervention:
Direct public provision & taxation.
Lindahl pricing (personalized prices; requires preference revelation).
Voting on discrete provision levels.
Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG)/Clarke tax mechanism.
Provision-point (Bagnoli–Lipman) mechanisms.
Steps:
Individuals state maximum WTP for each alternative.
Alternative with highest aggregate stated value is chosen.
Each individual pays a tax only if her report is pivotal (decisive); tax equals net external effect on others.
Key properties:
Payment never exceeds own stated value.
No incentive to misrepresent preferences (dominant-strategy truth-telling).
Numerical Illustration (3 voters A, B, C; alternatives X vs Y):
Truthful values (in €): A: (1,3),\ B:(3,2),\ C:(3.5,2) ⇒ \sum{X}=7.5, \sum{Y}=7 ⇒ X wins.
A is not pivotal ⇒ tax 0.
Remove B ⇒ sums 4.5 vs 5 → Y would win; hence B pivotal, pays tax 5-4.5 = 0.5.
Remove C ⇒ sums 4 vs 5 → Y wins; C pivotal, pays tax 5-4 = 1.
Misreporting (A pretending Y = 4) flips choice; now A pivotal & pays tax 2.5 > personal gain ⇒ lying unprofitable.
Specify cost/target for public good.
Collect voluntary pledges C_i.
If \sum C_i \ge \text{target} → good provided; if not → money-back guarantee.
Eliminates risk of being sole contributor; minimal strategic complexity.
Real-world use: Kickstarter campaigns, minimum-signatory climate treaties, charity drives.
Standard lab design (3 players):
Each endowed with 5 €; chooses contribution C_i \in [0,5] to a common pool.
Pool is doubled and evenly split.
Monetary payoff: Yi = 5 - \frac{1}{3}Ci + \frac{2}{3}(Cj+Ck).
Self-interest prediction: Ci = 0; Pareto-efficient: Ci=5 for all.
Classroom data (single shot): average contribution 3.57 € (≈ 71 % endowment); 43 % fully cooperative.
Robust experimental regularities:
One-shot mean ≈ 50 % of endowment.
Contributions decay across rounds in repeated games (learning to free-ride).
Stable groups (fixed partners) sustain higher cooperation.
Introducing costly punishment opportunities markedly raises contributions.
Large share of participants are conditional cooperators – contribute proportionally to others’ average.
Conditional cooperation documented as early as age 6.
Although theory predicts zero voluntary provision, human behaviour features altruism, norms, reciprocity & punishment.
Free-riding remains substantial; private mechanisms rarely reach full efficiency.
Central policy challenge: preference aggregation – obtaining reliable WTP data to meet Samuelson condition.
Clarke tax & related mechanisms are elegant but prone to:
High informational demands, complexity, administrative cost, potential collusion.
No universal solution; mix of regulation, property rights, taxation, and institution design needed.
Steer price schedule: P(N) = 120 - 2(N-1) for N=1,\ldots,6 (implied by table).
Government bond return: r = 0.12 per annum.