Increase in Domestic Demand:
An increase in consumption (C), investment (I), or government spending (G) raises output (Y).
However, this also deteriorates the trade balance due to increased imports.
Increase in Foreign Demand:
An increase in foreign demand (Y*) leads to higher export levels (X) and improvements in net exports (NX).
Notably, higher foreign demand contributes positively to the trade balance (↑ Y* → ↑X and NX ↑).
Implications of Demand Shocks:
Demand shocks in one country have a ripple effect on other countries through trade connections.
Economic interactions necessitate careful policy coordination which can be challenging to implement effectively.
Depreciation Effects on Trade Balance:
A real depreciation (↓ε) causes:
Increased exports (↑X) as foreign goods become cheaper.
Decreased imports (↓IM) as domestic goods become more expensive.
Leads to an increase in net exports (NX):
The M-L condition holds, supporting the increase in NX.
Marshall-Lerner Condition:
If satisfied, a real depreciation leads to increased net exports (NX).
Formula:
NX = X(Y*, ε) - IM(Y, ε)
Effects of Real Depreciation:
A real depreciation (↓ε) results in:
An upward shift in the NX curve at every output level.
Increased demand (Z) leading to shifts in output (Y to Y‘).
Outcomes include ↑Y and ↑NX along with a reduction in purchasing power for domestic consumers due to more expensive imports.
Scenario:
Given starting point A (Y = Yn) with a trade deficit (BC), objectives include:
Reducing trade deficit without affecting Y.
Policy Combination:
Implement real depreciation (↓ε) to boost NX while managing output (↑Y to A‘).
Combine with contractionary fiscal policy (↓G) to bring Z down, ensuring final equilibrium leading to NX increase without changing Y (final at B).
Greece's CA Deficit Trends:
CA deficit rose notably from 2000 onwards, peaking at almost 15% of GDP.
Improvement observed by 2018, but mainly due to a 30% decrease in output (Y) which decreased imports (IM) by 36%.
Tied to the euro, Greece had limited ability to depreciate (↓ε) without decreasing wages and prices for competitiveness.
Expectations:
As Y begins to recover, forecasts suggest CA deficits might re-emerge.
Current Account Balance Fundamentals:
In an open economy, investment (I) can be funded by both domestic and external savings.
Equilibrium condition involves:
Y = C + I + G + NX
Adjustments highlighting the necessity of external savings.
Current Account Balance Dynamics:
Rearranged, the current account balance (CA) reflects savings (S) and investment:
CA = S + T - G - I
Key insight:
An increase in investment must align with increases in savings (either private, public, or external) or result in a decrease in CA.
Capital Flows and Short-Run Equilibrium:
Variations in the current account are interconnected with savings and investment patterns.
Integration of findings into IS-LM to analyze short-run output fluctuations and impacts on economic models (IS-LM-UIP).
Key Equations include:
IS: Y = C(Y-T) + I(Y, r+x) + G + NX(Y, Y*, ε)
LM: r = 𝑟̅
UIP: i*−i = EM = $