Bargaining and Economic Allocations
Bargaining over the Surplus
- Coercive Allocations vs. Voluntary Allocations
- Coercive Allocations:
- If Bruno can coerce Angela, he maximizes the distance between Angela's feasible frontier and her survival constraint.
- Example allocation (B):
- Angela: 13 hours of leisure, 11 hours of work
- Production: 10 bushels
- Bruno takes 6 bushels, leaving Angela with 4 (survival minimal).
- Voluntary Allocations:
- If Angela can reject Bruno’s offer, he maximizes the distance between her feasible frontier and her reservation indifference curve.
- Example allocation (D):
- Angela: 16 hours of leisure, 8 hours of work
- Production: 9 bushels
- Bruno charges 4.5 bushels in rent, leaving Angela with 4.5 bushels.
- Maximizing the Surplus:
- Voluntary agreements seek to optimize the surplus.
Historical Context of Coercion
- Slavery and Economic Rents (Pre and Post 1865):
- Until 1865, plantation owners used violent coercion to extract rents from slaves.
- After 1865, landlords used more voluntary agreements to extract economic rents from ex-slaves.
The 40 Acres and a Mule Initiative
- General Sherman’s Order (1865):
- Proposed grants of 40 acres and a mule as reparations to ex-slave families.
- Allowed for potential independence as farmers instead of sharecropping.
- Ultimately, lands were returned to former slave owners; ex-slaves remained landless.
- Value of this land today estimated at hundreds of thousands of dollars.
Economic Efficiency Curves
- Pareto Efficiency Curve:
- When Angela acts as an independent farmer, she selects allocation C.
- If she is landless, she may accept allocation D.
- Points between C and D are considered Pareto efficient.
- At allocation G, Angela may receive additional rent but reduce Bruno’s.
- Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) and Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT):
- MRS at D = MRT at C indicates economic efficiency.
The Role of Strikes in Bargaining
- Example of Bread and Roses Strike (1912):
- Striking workers succeeded in negotiating better wages for a reduced workday.
- Allocation F Post-Strike:
- New deal: 4 hours of work/day for 4.5 bushels (a form of minimum wage).
- Inefficient because: MRS ≠ MRT, total surplus less than the maximum.
Redistribution and Economic Dynamics
- To improve conditions post-strike, Angela could work more with allocations G and H being preferable to F.
- Potential allocation J could result in higher output, increasing both Angela's and Bruno's benefits while aiming for efficiency.
Efficiency vs Fairness in Allocations
- Determining Efficiency:
- Allocations D, G, H, and C are efficient, while E and F are not.
- Considerations of fairness and the allocation that distributes resources fairly must be examined.
Analysis of Economic Inequalities
- Technological advancements have not led to increased wages for British and U.S. workers over significant periods.
- Lessons Learned:
- Dominance in allocation power results in concentrated surplus capture by the powerful.
- Exploited groups can enhance their economic standing through political means.
- Reducing inequality may boost surplus without necessarily enhancing every party’s welfare (no Pareto improvement).
- Support for equity in institutions depends on collective views of fair practices and distribution.