The Effect of Labor’s Bargaining Power on Wealth Inequality in the UK, USA, and France
Introduction
- This paper analyzes the determinants of wealth inequality, focusing on the causal role of labor's bargaining power.
- The study examines the UK, USA, and France, noting similar trajectories in the top 1% share of wealth, with the USA experiencing the sharpest increase in inequality since the 1980s.
- Institutional and structural changes have impacted labor's bargaining power, with union density decreasing substantially since the 1980s in all three countries, except France.
Literature Review and Gaps
- Existing literature analyzes labor's bargaining power and its impact on personal income inequality, wage inequality, and the labor share of income.
- This paper addresses two main gaps in the literature concerning wealth inequality:
- Underdeveloped econometric analysis on the determinants of wealth inequality.
- Lack of exploration of the link between labor's bargaining power and wealth inequality.
Theoretical Framework
- The paper presents a theoretical analysis of the channels through which labor's bargaining power impacts wealth inequality.
- It uses a semi-structural vector autoregression analysis with data from the UK, the USA, and France for the period 1970–2019.
- The study identifies the effects of shocks to labor's bargaining on the top 1% share of wealth across the three countries.
- A short-run restrictions are used, assuming that indicators capturing bargaining power are contemporaneously exogenous to wealth inequality.
- The justifaction is that the political influence of the top 1% on labor institutions takes time to materialize.
Findings
- A positive shock to the bargaining power of labor significantly reduces top 1% wealth shares across all three countries.
- Shocks to labor's bargaining power explain 32% of the variation in top wealth shares in the UK, 8% in the USA, and 32% in France.
- The smaller proportion of variation explained in the USA is attributed to the higher volatility of wealth inequality.
- The theoretical overview of the components of wealth inequality and how they are impacted by labor's bargaining power are presented in Section 2.
- Data and estimation methodology in Sections 3 and 4.
- Estimation results and conclusions in Sections 5 and 6.
Components of Wealth Inequality
Wealth W_{t}^{f} of fractile f (e.g., top 1% wealthiest households) in period t is given by:
- (1) \ W{t}^{f} = W{t-1}^{f}(1 + q{t}^{f}) + s{t}^{f}Y{t}^{f} + h{t}^{f}
- q_{t}^{f}: return on wealth due to capital gains.
- Y_{t}^{f}: pre-tax personal income.
- s_{t}^{f}: saving rate.
- h_{t}^{f}: net inheritances, gifts, and inter vivos transfers.
The capital gains component (q_{t}^{f}) is a weighted change in the price of assets in a portfolio:
- (2) \ q{t}^{f} = \sum{j=1}^{J} (\frac{P{j,t} - P{j,t-1}}{P{j,t-1}}) \frac{A{j,t-1}^{f}}{W_{t-1}^{f}}
- A_{j,t}^{f}: asset j held by fractile f in period t.
Simplifying assumptions:
- There are only two assets: equities and housing.
- The composition of assets held by fractile f changes in line with the population.
- Top 1% capital gains approximate capital gains of stocks; aggregate capital gains approximate capital gains on housing.
From these assumptions:
- (3) \ q{t}^{f} \approx (\frac{P{\text{stocks},t} - P{\text{stocks},t-1}}{P{\text{stocks},t-1}})
- (4) \ q{t} \approx (\frac{P{\text{housing},t} - P{\text{housing},t-1}}{P{\text{housing},t-1}})
Integrating inheritance and income taxes:
- (5) \ s{t}^{f} = s{\text{post},t}^{f} - T_{y}^{f}
- s_{\text{post},t}^{f}: saving rate out of post-tax income.
- T_{y}^{f}: average income tax rate.
- (6) \ h{t}^{f} = h{\text{post},t}^{f}(1 - T_{h}^{f})
- h_{\text{post},t}^{f}: post-tax net transfers.
- T_{h}^{f}: average inheritance tax rate.
The law of motion for top wealth shares:
- (7) \ \frac{W{t}^{f}}{W{t}} = \frac{(1 + q{t}^{f}) \frac{W{t-1}^{f}}{W{t-1}} + s{t}^{f} \frac{Y{t}^{f}}{Y{t}} \frac{Y{t}}{W{t-1}} + \frac{h{t}^{f}}{W{t-1}}}{1 + q{t} + s{t}\frac{Y{t}}{W{t-1}} + \frac{h{t}}{W{t-1}}}
Focus on four main factors:
- Differential capital gains (q{t}^{f} - q{t}).
- Share of personal income going to the top 1% (\frac{Y{t}^{f}}{Y{t}}).
- Differential saving rates (s{t}^{f} - s{t}).
- Top 1% net inheritance, transfer and inter vivos flows as a ratio to aggregate wealth (\frac{h{t}^{f}}{W{t-1}}).
Impact of Labor Bargaining Power
A positive shock to labor's bargaining power impacts the top 1% share of income via:
- Wage inequality and top managerial pay: higher trade union density reduces top managerial pay.
- Decreasing the capital share of income: redistributes income from capital to labor.
A positive labor bargaining shock impacts differential capital gains via:
- Negative impact on stock prices: unionization negatively impacts stock prices.
- Increase in house prices: labor market insecurity impacts homeownership.
Impact of a positive labor bargaining shock on differential saving rates is ambiguous due to:
- Change in relative precautionary saving motives between the top 1% and the bottom 99%.
- Change in the distribution of income between the two groups.
A positive labor bargaining shock reduces inheritance flows to the top 1% via a political channel.
Technological change and globalization also influence these components of wealth inequality.
Data
- Data sources:
- World Inequality Database (WID) for top 1% of individuals and the share of pre-tax national income of the top 1% of the income distribution.
- Macro History Database (Jordà et al. 2019) for differential capital gains.
- EU KLEMS for technological change.
- KOF de jure measures of financial and trade globalization.
- WID for progressive taxation.
- Measures of labor’s bargaining power:
- Trade union density in the UK and USA.
- Collective bargaining coverage in France.
Estimation Methodology
Empirical methodology estimates the impact of a labor bargaining shock on wealth inequality using a semi-structural VAR model for each country.
Short-run restrictions are imposed via a Cholesky Decomposition.
Key assumption: trade union density and collective bargaining coverage are contemporaneously exogenous to wealth inequality and its components.
- The justification is that the reverse causality happens with a lag.
The data generating process is defined according to the following structural equation:
- (8) \ B{0}y{t} = B{1} + B{2}y{t-1} + B{3}y{t-2} + u{t}
- y_{t} is a K \times 1 vector of a set of determinants;
- B_{i} are the model coefficients, i = 0, \dots, p
- u_{t} is a K \times 1 vector of structural shocks.
Testing for non-fundamentalness and ensuring informational sufficiency of the labor bargaining shock.
Structural impulse response functions (IRF) and forecast error variance decompositions (FEVD) are presented.
Estimating the SVAR models in levels with an intercept.
Confidence interval bands are used to determine the significance, using conventional residual-based bootstrap confidence intervals
Estimation Results
- Labor bargaining shocks are significant across all three countries after 11 years: it explains 32% and 32% of variation in UK and France.
- The magnitude of the effects in the UK and France are almost identical.
- In the USA, labor bargaining shocks explain only 8% of the variation in top wealth shares after 11 years.
- A 1 percent-point increase in union density leads to a 0.29 percent-point and 0.32 percent-point decline in top wealth shares after 8 years in the UK and the USA, respectively.
- In France, a 1 percent-point increase in collective bargaining coverage leads to a 0.38 percent decline by the 8th year, and a bigger drop in the short run.
- Difference in the US due to higher volatility of wealth inequality.
- FEVD in Table 2 shows that bargaining shocks explain the same amount of variation in income inequality across all three countries.
Robustness Tests
- Reordering union density/collective bargaining coverage with respect to the control variables.
- Reducing the size of the system, dropping the least significant variable first.
- Replacing the de jure measure of financial globalization with a de jure measure of trade globalization.
- Replacing top inheritance tax rates with top income tax rates.
- Extending the dataset to estimate the model for the period of 1970–2019 rather than 1970 to 2015.
- Results are robust to alternative orderings, system sizes, and control variables.
Conclusion
- The bargaining power of labor is a significant and robust determinant of the top 1% wealth share across all the countries.
- A positive bargaining shock associated with a 1 percent-point increase in union density in the UK and USA leads to a 0.25 percent-point and 0.36 percent-point decline in top wealth shares after 10 years.
- A positive shock associated with a 1 percent-point increase in collective bargaining coverage in France leads to a much bigger drop in top wealth shares in the short run.
- After 11 years, labor’s bargaining power explains 32%, 8%, and 32% of the variation in top wealth shares in the UK, the USA, and France, respectively.