CP

Unit 5: Property and Power - Mutual Gains and Conflict

Institutions and Power

  • This unit transitions from individual decision-making to interactions within legal and institutional frameworks.
  • It covers institutions, power, Pareto efficiency, fairness, and how these elements shape economic outcomes and welfare.
  • Key concepts include Institutions, Power, Bargaining power, Pareto efficiency, Substantive and procedural concepts of fairness, Economic rent, Coercion and bargaining.

Institutions, Power, and Rent Distribution

  • Institutions: Formal and informal rules governing interactions and distribution of economic rents (surplus).
  • Power: The ability to achieve desired outcomes in interactions.
  • Property owners can exert bargaining power by:
    • Setting terms in a take-it-or-leave-it manner.
    • Bargaining with multiple workers, creating competition.
    • Imposing costs or threatening contract termination.

Property and Power in Capitalist Systems

  • Property ownership can grant power (e.g., employers setting wage terms).
  • Changes in labor supply/demand and new institutions (trade unions, voting rights) can shift bargaining power.
  • Monopolies can exert power over consumers.
  • Institutions in democratic societies protect against coercion and promote voluntary exchange.

Evaluating Institutions and Outcomes

  • Allocation: The outcome of an economic interaction.
    • Includes each person’s contribution, the project's product, and the distribution of the product.
  • Institutions and outcomes are evaluated based on efficiency and fairness.

Efficiency vs. Other Considerations

  • In economics, efficiency differs from engineering (sensible methods) and business (profitability).
  • Pareto Efficiency: An allocation where no alternative can make one person better off without harming another.
    • If an allocation is not Pareto efficient, it's considered inefficient.
    • The question "Is poverty efficient?" is posed.

Pareto and Efficiency

  • Vilfredo Pareto sought to establish economics and sociology as fact-based sciences.
  • Pareto Law: A small group holds most wealth (e.g., 80-20 rule).
  • Pareto argued people compete over shares of the pie, either through production or appropriation.
  • He is renowned for defining efficiency in economics.

Pareto Improvement

  • Pareto Improvement: A change that makes at least one person better off without harming anyone else.
    • No trade-off is involved.
  • If a Pareto improvement is possible, the initial allocation is Pareto inefficient.
  • Pareto efficient allocation: No Pareto improvements possible; any change involves a trade-off.

Pareto Efficiency Example: TV Time

  • Scenario: Two siblings with one TV, differing show preferences, and 4 hours of TV time.
  • Question: Is a 2-hour split Pareto efficient?
  • To determine, consider if alternative allocations lead to Pareto improvements.

Pareto Efficiency: TV Time Allocations

  • Allocating 3 hours to the brother and 1 to the sister isn't a Pareto improvement (sister is worse off).
  • Similarly, 2.5 hours to the sister and 1.5 to the brother isn't a Pareto improvement (brother is worse off).

Pareto Efficiency: Full Allocation

  • No TV time allocation can improve one sibling's situation without worsening the other's.
  • All allocations using the full 4 hours are Pareto efficient.

Pareto Efficiency: Book and Skateboard

  • Siblings Lisa (prefers books) and Bart (prefers skateboards) receive mislabeled presents.
  • Lisa gets a skateboard, Bart a book.
  • Question: Is this allocation Pareto efficient? Is a Pareto efficient allocation possible?

Achieving Pareto Efficiency

  • The Pareto efficient allocation: Lisa gets the book, and Bart gets the skateboard.

Mutually Beneficial Exchange

  • Children trading Halloween candy exemplify Pareto efficiency.
  • Trades improve one child’s utility without harming others.
  • The final distribution is Pareto-efficient, as mutually beneficial trades are exhausted.
  • Mutually beneficial exchanges indicate the original allocation was Pareto inefficient.

Prisoner's Dilemma

  • The Prisoner's Dilemma is presented with a payoff matrix for Anil and Bala using Integrated Pest Control (IPC) or Terminator.
  • The matrix shows payoffs for each combination of choices.
    • Anil IPC, Bala IPC: (3, 3)
    • Anil IPC, Bala Terminator: (1, 4)
    • Anil Terminator, Bala IPC: (4, 1)
    • Anil Terminator, Bala Terminator: (2, 2)

Efficiency in the Prisoner’s Dilemma

  • A social dilemma is a Nash equilibrium that is Pareto inefficient.
  • Figure 5.1 illustrates outcomes and their efficiency:
    • I,I (Both use IPC) is efficient.
    • I,T (Anil uses IPC, Bala uses Terminator) is efficient.
    • T,I (Anil uses Terminator, Bala uses IPC) is efficient.
    • T,T (Both use Terminator) is inefficient.

Pareto Criterion Limitations

  • The Pareto criterion doesn't determine the