Unit 5: Property and Power - Mutual Gains and Conflict
Institutions and Power
- This unit transitions from individual decision-making to interactions within legal and institutional frameworks.
- It covers institutions, power, Pareto efficiency, fairness, and how these elements shape economic outcomes and welfare.
- Key concepts include Institutions, Power, Bargaining power, Pareto efficiency, Substantive and procedural concepts of fairness, Economic rent, Coercion and bargaining.
Institutions, Power, and Rent Distribution
- Institutions: Formal and informal rules governing interactions and distribution of economic rents (surplus).
- Power: The ability to achieve desired outcomes in interactions.
- Property owners can exert bargaining power by:
- Setting terms in a take-it-or-leave-it manner.
- Bargaining with multiple workers, creating competition.
- Imposing costs or threatening contract termination.
Property and Power in Capitalist Systems
- Property ownership can grant power (e.g., employers setting wage terms).
- Changes in labor supply/demand and new institutions (trade unions, voting rights) can shift bargaining power.
- Monopolies can exert power over consumers.
- Institutions in democratic societies protect against coercion and promote voluntary exchange.
Evaluating Institutions and Outcomes
- Allocation: The outcome of an economic interaction.
- Includes each person’s contribution, the project's product, and the distribution of the product.
- Institutions and outcomes are evaluated based on efficiency and fairness.
Efficiency vs. Other Considerations
- In economics, efficiency differs from engineering (sensible methods) and business (profitability).
- Pareto Efficiency: An allocation where no alternative can make one person better off without harming another.
- If an allocation is not Pareto efficient, it's considered inefficient.
- The question "Is poverty efficient?" is posed.
Pareto and Efficiency
- Vilfredo Pareto sought to establish economics and sociology as fact-based sciences.
- Pareto Law: A small group holds most wealth (e.g., 80-20 rule).
- Pareto argued people compete over shares of the pie, either through production or appropriation.
- He is renowned for defining efficiency in economics.
Pareto Improvement
- Pareto Improvement: A change that makes at least one person better off without harming anyone else.
- No trade-off is involved.
- If a Pareto improvement is possible, the initial allocation is Pareto inefficient.
- Pareto efficient allocation: No Pareto improvements possible; any change involves a trade-off.
Pareto Efficiency Example: TV Time
- Scenario: Two siblings with one TV, differing show preferences, and 4 hours of TV time.
- Question: Is a 2-hour split Pareto efficient?
- To determine, consider if alternative allocations lead to Pareto improvements.
Pareto Efficiency: TV Time Allocations
- Allocating 3 hours to the brother and 1 to the sister isn't a Pareto improvement (sister is worse off).
- Similarly, 2.5 hours to the sister and 1.5 to the brother isn't a Pareto improvement (brother is worse off).
Pareto Efficiency: Full Allocation
- No TV time allocation can improve one sibling's situation without worsening the other's.
- All allocations using the full 4 hours are Pareto efficient.
Pareto Efficiency: Book and Skateboard
- Siblings Lisa (prefers books) and Bart (prefers skateboards) receive mislabeled presents.
- Lisa gets a skateboard, Bart a book.
- Question: Is this allocation Pareto efficient? Is a Pareto efficient allocation possible?
Achieving Pareto Efficiency
- The Pareto efficient allocation: Lisa gets the book, and Bart gets the skateboard.
Mutually Beneficial Exchange
- Children trading Halloween candy exemplify Pareto efficiency.
- Trades improve one child’s utility without harming others.
- The final distribution is Pareto-efficient, as mutually beneficial trades are exhausted.
- Mutually beneficial exchanges indicate the original allocation was Pareto inefficient.
Prisoner's Dilemma
- The Prisoner's Dilemma is presented with a payoff matrix for Anil and Bala using Integrated Pest Control (IPC) or Terminator.
- The matrix shows payoffs for each combination of choices.
- Anil IPC, Bala IPC: (3, 3)
- Anil IPC, Bala Terminator: (1, 4)
- Anil Terminator, Bala IPC: (4, 1)
- Anil Terminator, Bala Terminator: (2, 2)
Efficiency in the Prisoner’s Dilemma
- A social dilemma is a Nash equilibrium that is Pareto inefficient.
- Figure 5.1 illustrates outcomes and their efficiency:
- I,I (Both use IPC) is efficient.
- I,T (Anil uses IPC, Bala uses Terminator) is efficient.
- T,I (Anil uses Terminator, Bala uses IPC) is efficient.
- T,T (Both use Terminator) is inefficient.
Pareto Criterion Limitations
- The Pareto criterion doesn't determine the